General principles

Repec services, additional websites using repec.

  • RePEc help / FAQ
  • Getting material into RePEc
  • Contributing archives
  • RePEc history

Quick links

  • MPRA : Munich Personal RePEc Archive
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : working papers
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : articles
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : books
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : book chapters
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : software components
  • EconPapers |   IDEAS : authors
  • EDIRC : Economics institutions

How RePEc operates:

Every publisher or provider puts text files describing their publications on their own server. These files follow a simple but rigorous machine-readable syntax. They are then automatically mirrored and made available to the public on the various RePEc websites. Some RePEc services complement these data with additional information such as citations or author details. RePEc is thus a facilitator that organizes the data for others to use.

How you can use RePEc as a provider or publisher:

Join over 2000 providers and publishers to increase the visibility of your publications. Follow these step-by-step instructions to create your RePEc archive. They show how to quickly set up your RePEc archive on your http, https, or ftp server and describe the syntax of the required metadata for working papers, journal articles, books, chapters, and software. For the complete technical details on the infrastructure and the metadata, you can also read about the Guildford Protocol and ReDIF , the Research Documents Information Format.

How you can use RePEc as a reader:

You can explore economic literature on two RePEc services. On EconPapers and IDEAS , search and browse, or follow links to author profiles, references, citations, keywords, or classifications. You can get notifications of new material with two other RePEc services, NEP and MyIDEAS .

How you can use RePEc as an author:

With the RePEc Author Service , you can create a profile of your indexed works. This allows the other RePEc services to link your profile to your works and vice versa. You also get notifications about the visibility of your works and citations newly found by CitEc . And if your publisher does not participate in RePEc, you can upload missing items to MPRA , copyright permitting.

How you can use RePEc as an institution:

RePEc can help you make your working papers (pre-prints) more visible, track how your researchers publish, and provide metrics to evaluate impact.

How you can leverage RePEc data as a researcher:

Data assembled by RePEc can be used for many purposes. Examples are academic research, tracking how working papers get published, adding metrics to a website, and evaluating researchers or institutions. We have instructions on how to access the data, including through an API.

There is much more that RePEc can do for you. Below is a list of all the RePEc services:

-->
Authors in institutions lacking a participating RePEc archive can submit their papers to MPRA and get them included in the RePEc database.

Author registration and maintenance of a profile on RePEc.
The complete RePEc database at your disposal. Browse or search it all.
Economics at your fingertips. EconPapers provides access to all of RePEc. Browsing and searching available.

Directory of Economics institutions, with links to their members and publications listed on RePEc
New Economics Papers is a free email, RSS and Twitter/X notification service for new downloadable working papers from over 90 specific fields. Archives are also available.
Academic family tree for economics.
Detailed download and access statistics for RePEc items and authors.
Citation analysis from items in the RePEc database.
Rankings by co-authorship centrality for authors registered in the RePEc Author Service.
Hand-selected bibliography of articles and papers in economics.
Blog aggregator for discussion about economics research.
Service to annotate RePEc papers in PDF and establish scientific relationships between papers.
An effort to curtail plagiarism of RePEc contents.
  • Google Scholar
  • Microsoft Academic Search
  • OAISter/WORLDCAT
  • ResearchGate

Adding bibliographic information to RePEc

If you intend to contribute information about your publications to RePEc, you may read the above documents or use these step-by-step instructions or sample templates . The same instructions apply for commercial publishers or research institutes.

RePEc archive maintainers may also make good use of the template syntax and link checker , of tips and tricks and the FAQ .

RePEc emerged from the NetEc group , created in 1992, which received support for its WoPEc project between 1996-1999 by the Joint Information Systems Committee (JISC) of the UK Higher Education Funding Councils, as part of its Electronic Libraries Programme (eLib). RePEc was created in June 1997 to decentralize the work done by WoPEc and thus make it independent of grant needs. RePEc is then guaranteed to remain free for all parties.

Economic Studies

The Brookings Economic Studies program provides analysis of current and emerging economic issues to promote innovative and practical policy solutions.

  • About Economic Studies
  • Experts and staff
  • Explore research and commentary

The Brookings Economic Studies program provides analysis of current and emerging economic issues to promote innovative and practical policy solutions. Economic Studies scholars conduct rigorous research and policy analysis and communicate their findings to inform policymakers and the public in the areas of broad-based economic growth, economic opportunity and mobility, inclusive social policy, sound monetary and fiscal policy, and climate-resilient growth.

Latest research and commentary

Michael Navarrete

September 9, 2024

The Brookings Institution, Washington D.C.

10:00 am - 11:00 am EDT

Comfort Oshagbemi, Louise Sheiner

September 5, 2024

Online only

10:30 am - 12:00 pm EDT

The energy transition and workforce development in the US

1:00 pm - 3:30 pm EDT

View all upcoming Economic Studies events >>

Featured experts

In the news.

Ben Harris joins CNBC Squawk Box to discuss Vice President Kamala Harris’ economic agenda and her speech laying out plans to tackle price gouging and the U.S. housing shortage.

David Wessel joins PBS Newshour to discuss recent turbulence in the U.S. stock market, the significance of the Bank of Japan’s rate hike, and renewed fears of an economic slowdown.

David Wessel

Richard Frank speaks with Barron’s about the Medicare drug-price negotiation process, and how companies could try to make their drugs exempt.

Richard G. Frank

Lauren Bauer speaks with the New York Times about how a lack of affordable and available child care services could keep mothers from joining the workforce.

Lauren Bauer

Ben Harris lays out the economic policy priorities that Vice President Kamala Harris is most likely to advocate as she campaigns for president.

Research by Ben Harris and Robin Brooks on tightening sanctions on Russia’s oil fleet is cited in a story about the Treasury Department’s interest in new penalties.

David Wessel speaks with NPR Morning Edition about former President Donald Trump’s economic proposals, including extensions of his 2017 tax cuts and new tariffs.

A cooling economy “would reinforce their story that (interest rate) policy is restrictive.”

Donald Kohn

Wendy Edelberg discusses the near-term economic impact of President Biden’s border policies with Politico.

Wendy Edelberg

Ben Harris joins Yahoo! Finance to discuss the Federal Reserve’s battle against inflation, and how the Fed’s credibility could have a bad influence on consumer behavior.

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity

The Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (BPEA) is a semi-annual academic conference and journal that pairs rigorous research with real-time policy analysis to address the most urgent economic challenges of the day.

1:00 pm - 12:45 pm EDT

Samuel G. Hanson, Victoria Ivashina, Laura Nicolae, Jeremy C. Stein, Adi Sunderam, Daniel K. Tarullo

March 27, 2024

Stefanie Stantcheva

Andrew Atkeson, Stephen Kissler

Economic Studies Bulletin Weekly

An update with the latest research on taxes, business, health, and social policy from the Economic Studies program at Brookings.

Hutchins Roundup and Newsletter Weekly

New research on fiscal and monetary policy, along with periodic updates from the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy.

Brookings Center on Health Policy Update Monthly

An update from the Center on Health Policy at Brookings.

Center for Economic Security and Opportunity Newsletter Monthly

A newsletter that explores the most challenging U.S. social policy questions.

Center on Regulation and Markets Newsletter Periodically

An update on important regulatory actions taken by the U.S. federal government.

This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.

Already a subscriber? Manage your subscriptions

Brookings Podcast on Economic Activity 21 Episodes 4 Seasons

The Brookings Podcast on Economic Activity connects you to cutting edge economic policy research and the renowned economists who create it. Each episode features an…

Recession Remedies Podcast 11 Episodes Limited Series

Recession Remedies focused on the economic policy response to COVID-19 and lessons for future recessions. Expert guests joined host David Wessel, director of the Hutchins…

Select experts

Select program, select topics, select regions.

  • Search Menu
  • Sign in through your institution
  • Advance articles
  • Featured articles
  • Virtual Issues
  • Browse content in B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches
  • Browse content in B4 - Economic Methodology
  • B49 - Other
  • Browse content in C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods
  • Browse content in C0 - General
  • C01 - Econometrics
  • Browse content in C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General
  • C10 - General
  • C11 - Bayesian Analysis: General
  • C12 - Hypothesis Testing: General
  • C13 - Estimation: General
  • C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General
  • C15 - Statistical Simulation Methods: General
  • Browse content in C2 - Single Equation Models; Single Variables
  • C21 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions
  • C22 - Time-Series Models; Dynamic Quantile Regressions; Dynamic Treatment Effect Models; Diffusion Processes
  • C23 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C26 - Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimation
  • Browse content in C3 - Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models; Multiple Variables
  • C31 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions; Social Interaction Models
  • C33 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C34 - Truncated and Censored Models; Switching Regression Models
  • C35 - Discrete Regression and Qualitative Choice Models; Discrete Regressors; Proportions
  • C36 - Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimation
  • Browse content in C4 - Econometric and Statistical Methods: Special Topics
  • C41 - Duration Analysis; Optimal Timing Strategies
  • C44 - Operations Research; Statistical Decision Theory
  • Browse content in C5 - Econometric Modeling
  • C50 - General
  • C51 - Model Construction and Estimation
  • C52 - Model Evaluation, Validation, and Selection
  • C53 - Forecasting and Prediction Methods; Simulation Methods
  • C54 - Quantitative Policy Modeling
  • C55 - Large Data Sets: Modeling and Analysis
  • C57 - Econometrics of Games and Auctions
  • Browse content in C6 - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling
  • C61 - Optimization Techniques; Programming Models; Dynamic Analysis
  • C62 - Existence and Stability Conditions of Equilibrium
  • C63 - Computational Techniques; Simulation Modeling
  • C67 - Input-Output Models
  • C68 - Computable General Equilibrium Models
  • Browse content in C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory
  • C70 - General
  • C72 - Noncooperative Games
  • C73 - Stochastic and Dynamic Games; Evolutionary Games; Repeated Games
  • C78 - Bargaining Theory; Matching Theory
  • C79 - Other
  • Browse content in C8 - Data Collection and Data Estimation Methodology; Computer Programs
  • C83 - Survey Methods; Sampling Methods
  • Browse content in C9 - Design of Experiments
  • C90 - General
  • C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior
  • C92 - Laboratory, Group Behavior
  • C93 - Field Experiments
  • Browse content in D - Microeconomics
  • Browse content in D0 - General
  • D01 - Microeconomic Behavior: Underlying Principles
  • D02 - Institutions: Design, Formation, Operations, and Impact
  • D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics
  • D11 - Consumer Economics: Theory
  • D12 - Consumer Economics: Empirical Analysis
  • D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation
  • D14 - Household Saving; Personal Finance
  • D15 - Intertemporal Household Choice: Life Cycle Models and Saving
  • D18 - Consumer Protection
  • Browse content in D2 - Production and Organizations
  • D21 - Firm Behavior: Theory
  • D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis
  • D23 - Organizational Behavior; Transaction Costs; Property Rights
  • D24 - Production; Cost; Capital; Capital, Total Factor, and Multifactor Productivity; Capacity
  • D25 - Intertemporal Firm Choice: Investment, Capacity, and Financing
  • D29 - Other
  • Browse content in D3 - Distribution
  • D30 - General
  • D31 - Personal Income, Wealth, and Their Distributions
  • Browse content in D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design
  • D40 - General
  • D41 - Perfect Competition
  • D42 - Monopoly
  • D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection
  • D44 - Auctions
  • D47 - Market Design
  • Browse content in D5 - General Equilibrium and Disequilibrium
  • D50 - General
  • D51 - Exchange and Production Economies
  • D52 - Incomplete Markets
  • D53 - Financial Markets
  • D57 - Input-Output Tables and Analysis
  • D58 - Computable and Other Applied General Equilibrium Models
  • Browse content in D6 - Welfare Economics
  • D60 - General
  • D61 - Allocative Efficiency; Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • D62 - Externalities
  • D63 - Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
  • D64 - Altruism; Philanthropy
  • Browse content in D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making
  • D70 - General
  • D71 - Social Choice; Clubs; Committees; Associations
  • D72 - Political Processes: Rent-seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior
  • D73 - Bureaucracy; Administrative Processes in Public Organizations; Corruption
  • D74 - Conflict; Conflict Resolution; Alliances; Revolutions
  • D78 - Positive Analysis of Policy Formulation and Implementation
  • Browse content in D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty
  • D80 - General
  • D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty
  • D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information; Mechanism Design
  • D83 - Search; Learning; Information and Knowledge; Communication; Belief; Unawareness
  • D84 - Expectations; Speculations
  • D85 - Network Formation and Analysis: Theory
  • D86 - Economics of Contract: Theory
  • Browse content in D9 - Micro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • D90 - General
  • D91 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on Decision Making
  • D92 - Intertemporal Firm Choice, Investment, Capacity, and Financing
  • Browse content in E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Browse content in E0 - General
  • E03 - Behavioral Macroeconomics
  • Browse content in E1 - General Aggregative Models
  • E10 - General
  • E12 - Keynes; Keynesian; Post-Keynesian
  • E13 - Neoclassical
  • E17 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy
  • E20 - General
  • E21 - Consumption; Saving; Wealth
  • E22 - Investment; Capital; Intangible Capital; Capacity
  • E23 - Production
  • E24 - Employment; Unemployment; Wages; Intergenerational Income Distribution; Aggregate Human Capital; Aggregate Labor Productivity
  • E25 - Aggregate Factor Income Distribution
  • E26 - Informal Economy; Underground Economy
  • E27 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles
  • E30 - General
  • E31 - Price Level; Inflation; Deflation
  • E32 - Business Fluctuations; Cycles
  • E37 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E4 - Money and Interest Rates
  • E40 - General
  • E41 - Demand for Money
  • E42 - Monetary Systems; Standards; Regimes; Government and the Monetary System; Payment Systems
  • E43 - Interest Rates: Determination, Term Structure, and Effects
  • E44 - Financial Markets and the Macroeconomy
  • E49 - Other
  • Browse content in E5 - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit
  • E50 - General
  • E51 - Money Supply; Credit; Money Multipliers
  • E52 - Monetary Policy
  • E58 - Central Banks and Their Policies
  • Browse content in E6 - Macroeconomic Policy, Macroeconomic Aspects of Public Finance, and General Outlook
  • E60 - General
  • E61 - Policy Objectives; Policy Designs and Consistency; Policy Coordination
  • E62 - Fiscal Policy
  • E65 - Studies of Particular Policy Episodes
  • Browse content in E7 - Macro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • E70 - General
  • E71 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on the Macro Economy
  • Browse content in F - International Economics
  • Browse content in F1 - Trade
  • F10 - General
  • F11 - Neoclassical Models of Trade
  • F12 - Models of Trade with Imperfect Competition and Scale Economies; Fragmentation
  • F13 - Trade Policy; International Trade Organizations
  • F14 - Empirical Studies of Trade
  • F15 - Economic Integration
  • F16 - Trade and Labor Market Interactions
  • F17 - Trade Forecasting and Simulation
  • F18 - Trade and Environment
  • F19 - Other
  • Browse content in F2 - International Factor Movements and International Business
  • F20 - General
  • F21 - International Investment; Long-Term Capital Movements
  • F22 - International Migration
  • F23 - Multinational Firms; International Business
  • Browse content in F3 - International Finance
  • F30 - General
  • F31 - Foreign Exchange
  • F32 - Current Account Adjustment; Short-Term Capital Movements
  • F33 - International Monetary Arrangements and Institutions
  • F34 - International Lending and Debt Problems
  • F36 - Financial Aspects of Economic Integration
  • Browse content in F4 - Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance
  • F40 - General
  • F41 - Open Economy Macroeconomics
  • F42 - International Policy Coordination and Transmission
  • F43 - Economic Growth of Open Economies
  • F44 - International Business Cycles
  • Browse content in F5 - International Relations, National Security, and International Political Economy
  • F50 - General
  • F53 - International Agreements and Observance; International Organizations
  • Browse content in F6 - Economic Impacts of Globalization
  • F60 - General
  • F62 - Macroeconomic Impacts
  • F63 - Economic Development
  • F64 - Environment
  • F65 - Finance
  • Browse content in G - Financial Economics
  • Browse content in G0 - General
  • G01 - Financial Crises
  • G02 - Behavioral Finance: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in G1 - General Financial Markets
  • G10 - General
  • G11 - Portfolio Choice; Investment Decisions
  • G12 - Asset Pricing; Trading volume; Bond Interest Rates
  • G13 - Contingent Pricing; Futures Pricing
  • G14 - Information and Market Efficiency; Event Studies; Insider Trading
  • G15 - International Financial Markets
  • G18 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G2 - Financial Institutions and Services
  • G20 - General
  • G21 - Banks; Depository Institutions; Micro Finance Institutions; Mortgages
  • G22 - Insurance; Insurance Companies; Actuarial Studies
  • G23 - Non-bank Financial Institutions; Financial Instruments; Institutional Investors
  • G24 - Investment Banking; Venture Capital; Brokerage; Ratings and Ratings Agencies
  • G28 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G3 - Corporate Finance and Governance
  • G30 - General
  • G31 - Capital Budgeting; Fixed Investment and Inventory Studies; Capacity
  • G32 - Financing Policy; Financial Risk and Risk Management; Capital and Ownership Structure; Value of Firms; Goodwill
  • G33 - Bankruptcy; Liquidation
  • G34 - Mergers; Acquisitions; Restructuring; Corporate Governance
  • G38 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G4 - Behavioral Finance
  • G40 - General
  • G41 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on Decision Making in Financial Markets
  • Browse content in H - Public Economics
  • Browse content in H0 - General
  • H00 - General
  • Browse content in H1 - Structure and Scope of Government
  • H11 - Structure, Scope, and Performance of Government
  • Browse content in H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H20 - General
  • H21 - Efficiency; Optimal Taxation
  • H23 - Externalities; Redistributive Effects; Environmental Taxes and Subsidies
  • H24 - Personal Income and Other Nonbusiness Taxes and Subsidies; includes inheritance and gift taxes
  • H25 - Business Taxes and Subsidies
  • H26 - Tax Evasion and Avoidance
  • Browse content in H3 - Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents
  • H30 - General
  • H31 - Household
  • Browse content in H4 - Publicly Provided Goods
  • H41 - Public Goods
  • H42 - Publicly Provided Private Goods
  • Browse content in H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies
  • H50 - General
  • H51 - Government Expenditures and Health
  • H52 - Government Expenditures and Education
  • H53 - Government Expenditures and Welfare Programs
  • H55 - Social Security and Public Pensions
  • H56 - National Security and War
  • Browse content in H6 - National Budget, Deficit, and Debt
  • H60 - General
  • H63 - Debt; Debt Management; Sovereign Debt
  • Browse content in H7 - State and Local Government; Intergovernmental Relations
  • H71 - State and Local Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H75 - State and Local Government: Health; Education; Welfare; Public Pensions
  • Browse content in H8 - Miscellaneous Issues
  • H81 - Governmental Loans; Loan Guarantees; Credits; Grants; Bailouts
  • Browse content in I - Health, Education, and Welfare
  • Browse content in I0 - General
  • I00 - General
  • Browse content in I1 - Health
  • I10 - General
  • I11 - Analysis of Health Care Markets
  • I12 - Health Behavior
  • I13 - Health Insurance, Public and Private
  • I14 - Health and Inequality
  • I15 - Health and Economic Development
  • I18 - Government Policy; Regulation; Public Health
  • Browse content in I2 - Education and Research Institutions
  • I20 - General
  • I21 - Analysis of Education
  • I22 - Educational Finance; Financial Aid
  • I23 - Higher Education; Research Institutions
  • I24 - Education and Inequality
  • I25 - Education and Economic Development
  • I26 - Returns to Education
  • I28 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in I3 - Welfare, Well-Being, and Poverty
  • I30 - General
  • I31 - General Welfare
  • I32 - Measurement and Analysis of Poverty
  • I38 - Government Policy; Provision and Effects of Welfare Programs
  • I39 - Other
  • Browse content in J - Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Browse content in J0 - General
  • J00 - General
  • J01 - Labor Economics: General
  • J08 - Labor Economics Policies
  • Browse content in J1 - Demographic Economics
  • J10 - General
  • J11 - Demographic Trends, Macroeconomic Effects, and Forecasts
  • J12 - Marriage; Marital Dissolution; Family Structure; Domestic Abuse
  • J13 - Fertility; Family Planning; Child Care; Children; Youth
  • J14 - Economics of the Elderly; Economics of the Handicapped; Non-Labor Market Discrimination
  • J15 - Economics of Minorities, Races, Indigenous Peoples, and Immigrants; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J16 - Economics of Gender; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J17 - Value of Life; Forgone Income
  • Browse content in J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor
  • J20 - General
  • J21 - Labor Force and Employment, Size, and Structure
  • J22 - Time Allocation and Labor Supply
  • J23 - Labor Demand
  • J24 - Human Capital; Skills; Occupational Choice; Labor Productivity
  • Browse content in J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs
  • J30 - General
  • J31 - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
  • J32 - Nonwage Labor Costs and Benefits; Retirement Plans; Private Pensions
  • J33 - Compensation Packages; Payment Methods
  • J38 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J4 - Particular Labor Markets
  • J41 - Labor Contracts
  • J42 - Monopsony; Segmented Labor Markets
  • J44 - Professional Labor Markets; Occupational Licensing
  • J47 - Coercive Labor Markets
  • Browse content in J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining
  • J50 - General
  • J52 - Dispute Resolution: Strikes, Arbitration, and Mediation; Collective Bargaining
  • Browse content in J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers
  • J60 - General
  • J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers
  • J62 - Job, Occupational, and Intergenerational Mobility
  • J63 - Turnover; Vacancies; Layoffs
  • J64 - Unemployment: Models, Duration, Incidence, and Job Search
  • J65 - Unemployment Insurance; Severance Pay; Plant Closings
  • J68 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J7 - Labor Discrimination
  • J71 - Discrimination
  • Browse content in J8 - Labor Standards: National and International
  • J81 - Working Conditions
  • J82 - Labor Force Composition
  • J83 - Workers' Rights
  • Browse content in K - Law and Economics
  • Browse content in K0 - General
  • K00 - General
  • Browse content in K1 - Basic Areas of Law
  • K14 - Criminal Law
  • Browse content in K3 - Other Substantive Areas of Law
  • K31 - Labor Law
  • K33 - International Law
  • K35 - Personal Bankruptcy Law
  • Browse content in K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior
  • K40 - General
  • K41 - Litigation Process
  • K42 - Illegal Behavior and the Enforcement of Law
  • Browse content in L - Industrial Organization
  • Browse content in L0 - General
  • L00 - General
  • Browse content in L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance
  • L10 - General
  • L11 - Production, Pricing, and Market Structure; Size Distribution of Firms
  • L12 - Monopoly; Monopolization Strategies
  • L13 - Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets
  • L14 - Transactional Relationships; Contracts and Reputation; Networks
  • L15 - Information and Product Quality; Standardization and Compatibility
  • Browse content in L2 - Firm Objectives, Organization, and Behavior
  • L20 - General
  • L22 - Firm Organization and Market Structure
  • L23 - Organization of Production
  • L25 - Firm Performance: Size, Diversification, and Scope
  • Browse content in L3 - Nonprofit Organizations and Public Enterprise
  • L31 - Nonprofit Institutions; NGOs; Social Entrepreneurship
  • Browse content in L4 - Antitrust Issues and Policies
  • L41 - Monopolization; Horizontal Anticompetitive Practices
  • L42 - Vertical Restraints; Resale Price Maintenance; Quantity Discounts
  • L43 - Legal Monopolies and Regulation or Deregulation
  • Browse content in L5 - Regulation and Industrial Policy
  • L50 - General
  • L51 - Economics of Regulation
  • Browse content in L6 - Industry Studies: Manufacturing
  • L60 - General
  • L62 - Automobiles; Other Transportation Equipment; Related Parts and Equipment
  • L63 - Microelectronics; Computers; Communications Equipment
  • L65 - Chemicals; Rubber; Drugs; Biotechnology
  • Browse content in L7 - Industry Studies: Primary Products and Construction
  • L71 - Mining, Extraction, and Refining: Hydrocarbon Fuels
  • Browse content in L8 - Industry Studies: Services
  • L81 - Retail and Wholesale Trade; e-Commerce
  • L82 - Entertainment; Media
  • L86 - Information and Internet Services; Computer Software
  • Browse content in L9 - Industry Studies: Transportation and Utilities
  • L93 - Air Transportation
  • L94 - Electric Utilities
  • L96 - Telecommunications
  • Browse content in M - Business Administration and Business Economics; Marketing; Accounting; Personnel Economics
  • Browse content in M0 - General
  • M00 - General
  • Browse content in M1 - Business Administration
  • M11 - Production Management
  • M14 - Corporate Culture; Social Responsibility
  • Browse content in M2 - Business Economics
  • M21 - Business Economics
  • Browse content in M3 - Marketing and Advertising
  • M31 - Marketing
  • M37 - Advertising
  • Browse content in M5 - Personnel Economics
  • M50 - General
  • M51 - Firm Employment Decisions; Promotions
  • M52 - Compensation and Compensation Methods and Their Effects
  • M54 - Labor Management
  • M55 - Labor Contracting Devices
  • Browse content in N - Economic History
  • Browse content in N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Industrial Structure; Growth; Fluctuations
  • N10 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N13 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N2 - Financial Markets and Institutions
  • N20 - General, International, or Comparative
  • Browse content in N3 - Labor and Consumers, Demography, Education, Health, Welfare, Income, Wealth, Religion, and Philanthropy
  • N30 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N31 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N32 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N33 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N34 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in N4 - Government, War, Law, International Relations, and Regulation
  • N42 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N43 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N44 - Europe: 1913-
  • N45 - Asia including Middle East
  • Browse content in N9 - Regional and Urban History
  • N90 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N92 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N94 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth
  • Browse content in O1 - Economic Development
  • O10 - General
  • O11 - Macroeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O12 - Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O13 - Agriculture; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Other Primary Products
  • O14 - Industrialization; Manufacturing and Service Industries; Choice of Technology
  • O15 - Human Resources; Human Development; Income Distribution; Migration
  • O16 - Financial Markets; Saving and Capital Investment; Corporate Finance and Governance
  • O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors; Shadow Economy; Institutional Arrangements
  • O18 - Urban, Rural, Regional, and Transportation Analysis; Housing; Infrastructure
  • Browse content in O2 - Development Planning and Policy
  • O23 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Development
  • Browse content in O3 - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights
  • O30 - General
  • O31 - Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives
  • O32 - Management of Technological Innovation and R&D
  • O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes
  • O34 - Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
  • O38 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity
  • O40 - General
  • O41 - One, Two, and Multisector Growth Models
  • O42 - Monetary Growth Models
  • O43 - Institutions and Growth
  • O44 - Environment and Growth
  • O47 - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity; Cross-Country Output Convergence
  • Browse content in O5 - Economywide Country Studies
  • O51 - U.S.; Canada
  • O55 - Africa
  • Browse content in P - Economic Systems
  • Browse content in P0 - General
  • P00 - General
  • Browse content in P1 - Capitalist Systems
  • P16 - Political Economy
  • Browse content in P2 - Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies
  • P26 - Political Economy; Property Rights
  • P4 - Other Economic Systems
  • Browse content in Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics
  • Browse content in Q1 - Agriculture
  • Q15 - Land Ownership and Tenure; Land Reform; Land Use; Irrigation; Agriculture and Environment
  • Q16 - R&D; Agricultural Technology; Biofuels; Agricultural Extension Services
  • Browse content in Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q33 - Resource Booms
  • Browse content in Q4 - Energy
  • Q41 - Demand and Supply; Prices
  • Q43 - Energy and the Macroeconomy
  • Browse content in Q5 - Environmental Economics
  • Q51 - Valuation of Environmental Effects
  • Q52 - Pollution Control Adoption Costs; Distributional Effects; Employment Effects
  • Q53 - Air Pollution; Water Pollution; Noise; Hazardous Waste; Solid Waste; Recycling
  • Q54 - Climate; Natural Disasters; Global Warming
  • Q55 - Technological Innovation
  • Q56 - Environment and Development; Environment and Trade; Sustainability; Environmental Accounts and Accounting; Environmental Equity; Population Growth
  • Q58 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R1 - General Regional Economics
  • R10 - General
  • R11 - Regional Economic Activity: Growth, Development, Environmental Issues, and Changes
  • R12 - Size and Spatial Distributions of Regional Economic Activity
  • R13 - General Equilibrium and Welfare Economic Analysis of Regional Economies
  • R15 - Econometric and Input-Output Models; Other Models
  • Browse content in R2 - Household Analysis
  • R21 - Housing Demand
  • R23 - Regional Migration; Regional Labor Markets; Population; Neighborhood Characteristics
  • Browse content in R3 - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location
  • R31 - Housing Supply and Markets
  • R33 - Nonagricultural and Nonresidential Real Estate Markets
  • Browse content in R4 - Transportation Economics
  • R41 - Transportation: Demand, Supply, and Congestion; Travel Time; Safety and Accidents; Transportation Noise
  • R48 - Government Pricing and Policy
  • Browse content in R5 - Regional Government Analysis
  • R51 - Finance in Urban and Rural Economies
  • Browse content in Z - Other Special Topics
  • Browse content in Z1 - Cultural Economics; Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology
  • Z10 - General
  • Z12 - Religion
  • Z13 - Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology; Social and Economic Stratification
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • About The Review of Economic Studies
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Highly Cited Articles

The Review of Economic Studies is a premier journal in the field of economic research, with a reputation for publishing path-breaking papers in theoretical and applied economics. The quality and influence of research published in the journal is demonstrated by our latest Impact Factor, which shows that articles published in The Review remain highly read and cited by researchers in the field.

Join us in celebrating this continued achievement by reading a collection of some of the most highly cited articles we have published in the past few years. Use this research to support your current work, or get up to date with important discussions in economics. Papers are free to access online until the end of 2021.

Interested in submitting to The Review of Economic Studies?

The Review is committed to continuing to publish strong papers in all areas of economics. The Editors aim to provide an efficient and high-quality review process to The Review 's authors. Where articles are sent out for full review, authors receive careful reports and feedback.

Read our author guidelines to find out how to submit your work, and join a flourishing community of researchers publishing in the journal.

  • Recommend to your Library
  • Journals Career Network

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1467-937X
  • Print ISSN 0034-6527
  • Copyright © 2024 Review of Economic Studies Ltd
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals

Economics articles from across Nature Portfolio

Latest research and reviews, non-financial information farsightedness and capital market information efficiency.

  • Chuan Zhang
  • Yueyun Wang

research studies about economics

Globalization’s effects on South Asia’s carbon emissions, 1996–2019: a multidimensional panel data perspective via FGLS

  • Musarat Abbas
  • Michael L. Lahr

research studies about economics

Spatial heterogeneity analysis of biased land resource supply policies on housing prices and innovation efficiency

  • Shixiang Chen

research studies about economics

Under the context of competition between platform sales and live streaming sales, who has the pricing power of products?

  • Shizhen Bai

Rule of law, corruption and transparency impacts on green growth of East Asian economies

  • Weifeng Yan

research studies about economics

Impact of the degree of agricultural green production technology adoption on income: evidence from Sichuan citrus growers

Advertisement

News and Comment

research studies about economics

Both downsizing and improvements to livestock systems are needed to stay within planetary boundaries

A focus on improvements to livestock production limits the scope for food systems transformation. Research, policy and industry must adopt measures to downsize livestock production and consumption to meet sustainability targets and facilitate a just transition.

  • Irina Herzon
  • Rachel Mazac

research studies about economics

The rise of teamwork and career prospects in academic science

The rise in team size in academic science has generated an unintended side effect: junior scientists are less likely to secure research funding or obtain tenure and are more likely to leave academia.

  • Mabel Andalón
  • Catherine de Fontenay
  • Kwanghui Lim

research studies about economics

What counts as climate mitigation costs

Technological feasibility and project-level economic costs are only two important considerations in previous estimations of climate mitigation costs. Now a study shows how political and institutional constraints matter too.

  • Gernot Wagner

research studies about economics

Removing development incentives in risky areas reduces climate damages and yields co-benefits

Eliminating government infrastructure spending, public disaster insurance and post-disaster aid in high-risk coastal areas reduces development there and leads to lower flood damages and higher property values on nearby lands. The strategic withdrawal of development incentives could be used more broadly to reduce climate risks.

  • Hannah Druckenmiller
  • Yanjun (Penny) Liao

research studies about economics

Bronze Age Europeans exhibited modern economic behaviour

The foundations of modern economic systems are rooted in the economic behaviour of contemporary humans, and ‘primitive’ societies have been assumed not to fit standard economic theory. But an analysis of metal fragments — effectively, money — shows that modern-style economic behaviour can be identified at least as far back as 3,500 years ago.

research studies about economics

Connecting ecosystem services research and human rights to revamp the application of the precautionary principle

With ecosystem services (ES) vital for human wellbeing 1 , the protection of nature is a human rights matter. We outline how recent advances in international human rights law should inform a revamp of how precaution is applied within environmental decision-making. Critically, precautionary decision-making must evolve to make use of best-available evidence, including novel ES research approaches, to assess ‘foreseeable’ harms to all aspects of human wellbeing that are protected as human rights.

  • Holly J. Niner
  • Elisa Morgera
  • Siân E. Rees

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

research studies about economics

Take a look at the latest research from MIT Economics faculty, including published work and newly-released working papers.

Working Papers

Incentive-compatible unemployment reinsurance for the euro area, capital and wages.

Risky Business: Why Insurance Markets Fail and What to Do About It

Risky Business: Why Insurance Markets Fail and What To Do About It

Cover of Cooking to Save Your Life with an illustration by Cheyenne Olivier of Abhijit cooking surrounded by others

Cooking to Save Your Life

Published papers, climate change, directed innovation, and energy transition: the long-run consequences of the shale gas revolution, a task-based approach to inequality.

Economics Department students and faculty

Labs and Centers

Research news.

research studies about economics

Through econometrics, Isaiah Andrews is making research more robust

Michael D Whinston

Michael D Whinston receives the 2024 Jean-Jacques Laffont Prize

Suggestions or feedback?

MIT News | Massachusetts Institute of Technology

  • Machine learning
  • Sustainability
  • Black holes
  • Classes and programs

Departments

  • Aeronautics and Astronautics
  • Brain and Cognitive Sciences
  • Architecture
  • Political Science
  • Mechanical Engineering

Centers, Labs, & Programs

  • Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL)
  • Picower Institute for Learning and Memory
  • Lincoln Laboratory
  • School of Architecture + Planning
  • School of Engineering
  • School of Humanities, Arts, and Social Sciences
  • Sloan School of Management
  • School of Science
  • MIT Schwarzman College of Computing

The power of economics to explain and shape the world

Press contact :.

Photo of Abijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo standing side-by-side against a blurred background

Previous image Next image

Nobel Prize-winning economist Esther Duflo sympathizes with students who have no interest in her field. She was such a student herself — until an undergraduate research post gave her the chance to learn first-hand that economists address many of the major issues facing human and planetary well-being. “Most people have a wrong view of what economics is. They just see economists on television discussing what’s going to happen to the stock market,” says Duflo, the Abdul Latif Jameel Professor of Poverty Alleviation and Development Economics. “But what people do in the field is very broad. Economists grapple with the real world and with the complexity that goes with it.”

That’s why this year Duflo has teamed up with Professor Abhijit Banerjee to offer 14.009 (Economics and Society’s Greatest Problems), a first-year discovery subject — a class type designed to give undergraduates a low-pressure, high-impact way to explore a field. In this case, they are exploring the range of issues that economists engage with every day: the economic dimensions of climate change, international trade, racism, justice, education, poverty, health care, social preferences, and economic growth are just a few of the topics the class covers. “We think it’s pretty important that the first exposure to economics is via issues,” Duflo says. “If you first get exposed to economics via models, these models necessarily have to be very simplified, and then students get the idea that economics is a simplistic view of the world that can’t explain much.” Arguably, Duflo and Banerjee have been disproving that view throughout their careers. In 2003, the pair founded MIT’s Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, a leading antipoverty research network that provides scientific evidence on what methods actually work to alleviate poverty — which enables governments and nongovernmental organizations to implement truly effective programs and social policies. And, in 2019 they won the Nobel Prize in economics (together with Michael Kremer of the University of Chicago) for their innovative work applying laboratory-style randomized, controlled trials to research a wide range of topics implicated in global poverty. “Super cool”

First-year Jean Billa, one of the students in 14.009, says, “Economics isn’t just about how money flows, but about how people react to certain events. That was an interesting discovery for me.”

It’s also precisely the lesson Banerjee and Duflo hoped students would take away from 14.009, a class that centers on weekly in-person discussions of the professors’ recorded lectures — many of which align with chapters in Banerjee and Duflo’s book “Good Economics for Hard Times” (Public Affairs, 2019). Classes typically start with a poll in which the roughly 100 enrolled students can register their views on that week’s topic. Then, students get to discuss the issue, says senior Dina Atia, teaching assistant for the class. Noting that she finds it “super cool” that Nobelists are teaching MIT’s first-year students, Atia points out that both Duflo and Banerjee have also made themselves available to chat with students after class. “They’re definitely extending themselves,” she says. “We want the students to get excited about economics so they want to know more,” says Banerjee, the Ford Foundation International Professor of Economics, “because this is a field that can help us address some of the biggest problems society faces.”   Using natural experiments to test theories

Early in the term, for example, the topic was migration. In the lecture, Duflo points out that migration policies are often impacted by the fear that unskilled migrants will overwhelm a region, taking jobs from residents and demanding social services. Yet, migrant flows in normal years represent just 3 percent of the world population. “There is no flood. There is no vast movement of migrants,” she says. Duflo then explains that economists were able to learn a lot about migration thanks to a “natural experiment,” the Mariel boat lift. This 1980 event brought roughly 125,000 unskilled Cubans to Florida over a matter a months, enabling economists to study the impacts of a sudden wave of migration. Duflo says a look at real wages before and after the migration showed no significant impacts. “It was interesting to see that most theories about immigrants were not justified,” Billa says. “That was a real-life situation, and the results showed that even a massive wave of immigration didn’t change work in the city [Miami].”

Question assumptions, find the facts in data Since this is a broad survey course, there is always more to unpack. The goal, faculty say, is simply to help students understand the power of economics to explain and shape the world. “We are going so fast from topic to topic, I don’t expect them to retain all the information,” Duflo says. Instead, students are expected to gain an appreciation for a way of thinking. “Economics is about questioning everything — questioning assumptions you don’t even know are assumptions and being sophisticated about looking at data to uncover the facts.” To add impact, Duflo says she and Banerjee tie lessons to current events and dive more deeply into a few economic studies. One class, for example, focused on the unequal burden the Covid-19 pandemic has placed on different demographic groups and referenced research by Harvard University professor Marcella Alsan, who won a MacArthur Fellowship this fall for her work studying the impact of racism on health disparities.

Duflo also revealed that at the beginning of the pandemic, she suspected that mistrust of the health-care system could prevent Black Americans from taking certain measures to protect themselves from the virus. What she discovered when she researched the topic, however, was that political considerations outweighed racial influences as a predictor of behavior. “The lesson for you is, it’s good to question your assumptions,” she told the class. “Students should ideally understand, by the end of class, why it’s important to ask questions and what they can teach us about the effectiveness of policy and economic theory,” Banerjee says. “We want people to discover the range of economics and to understand how economists look at problems.”

Story by MIT SHASS Communications Editorial and design director: Emily Hiestand Senior writer: Kathryn O'Neill

Share this news article on:

Press mentions.

Prof. Esther Duflo will present her research on poverty reduction and her “proposal for a global minimum tax on billionaires and increased corporate levies to G-20 finance chiefs,” reports Andrew Rosati for Bloomberg. “The plan calls for redistributing the revenues to low- and middle-income nations to compensate for lives lost due to a warming planet,” writes Rosati. “It also adds to growing calls to raise taxes on the world’s wealthiest to help its most needy.”

Previous item Next item

Related Links

  • Class 14.009 (Economics and Society’s Greatest Problems)
  • Esther Duflo
  • Abhijit Banerjee
  • Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab
  • Department of Economics
  • Video: "Lighting the Path"

Related Topics

  • Education, teaching, academics
  • Climate change
  • Immigration
  • Social justice
  • Health care
  • School of Humanities Arts and Social Sciences

Related Articles

Asu Ozdaglar,

Popular new major blends technical skills and human-centered applications

migration group

Report: Economics drives migration from Central America to the U.S.

MIT economists Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo stand outside their home after learning that they have been named co-winners of the 2019 Nobel Prize in economic sciences. They will share the prize with Michael Kremer of Harvard University.

MIT economists Esther Duflo and Abhijit Banerjee win Nobel Prize

More mit news.

Two by four grid of headshots of SHASS faculty

Meet the 2024 tenured professors in the MIT School of Humanities, Arts, and Social Sciences

Read full story →

An illustration of two hands, each holding matching pills. One is labeled PLACEBO.

Harnessing the power of placebo for pain relief

MIT columns behind flowering tree branches

School of Engineering faculty and staff receive awards in spring 2024

Fourteen graduates wear white navy uniforms on the steps of Building 5.

MIT graduate programs empower the next generation of naval leaders

3 students gather around an orange motorcycle with a partially exposed design, showcasing intricate mechanical components

MIT students combat climate anxiety through extracurricular teams

Vladimir Bulović, Denise Milan, and Frank Wilczek pose together in front of a staircase, with framed artwork on the walls.

Tools for making imagination blossom at MIT.nano

  • More news on MIT News homepage →

Massachusetts Institute of Technology 77 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA, USA

  • Map (opens in new window)
  • Events (opens in new window)
  • People (opens in new window)
  • Careers (opens in new window)
  • Accessibility
  • Social Media Hub
  • MIT on Facebook
  • MIT on YouTube
  • MIT on Instagram
  • Architecture and Design
  • Asian and Pacific Studies
  • Business and Economics
  • Classical and Ancient Near Eastern Studies
  • Computer Sciences
  • Cultural Studies
  • Engineering
  • General Interest
  • Geosciences
  • Industrial Chemistry
  • Islamic and Middle Eastern Studies
  • Jewish Studies
  • Library and Information Science, Book Studies
  • Life Sciences
  • Linguistics and Semiotics
  • Literary Studies
  • Materials Sciences
  • Mathematics
  • Social Sciences
  • Sports and Recreation
  • Theology and Religion
  • Publish your article
  • The role of authors
  • Promoting your article
  • Abstracting & indexing
  • Publishing Ethics
  • Why publish with De Gruyter
  • How to publish with De Gruyter
  • Our book series
  • Our subject areas
  • Your digital product at De Gruyter
  • Contribute to our reference works
  • Product information
  • Tools & resources
  • Product Information
  • Promotional Materials
  • Orders and Inquiries
  • FAQ for Library Suppliers and Book Sellers
  • Repository Policy
  • Free access policy
  • Open Access agreements
  • Database portals
  • For Authors
  • Customer service
  • People + Culture
  • Journal Management
  • How to join us
  • Working at De Gruyter
  • Mission & Vision
  • De Gruyter Foundation
  • De Gruyter Ebound
  • Our Responsibility
  • Partner publishers

research studies about economics

Your purchase has been completed. Your documents are now available to view.

Methods Used in Economic Research: An Empirical Study of Trends and Levels

The methods used in economic research are analyzed on a sample of all 3,415 regular research papers published in 10 general interest journals every 5th year from 1997 to 2017. The papers are classified into three main groups by method: theory, experiments, and empirics. The theory and empirics groups are almost equally large. Most empiric papers use the classical method, which derives an operational model from theory and runs regressions. The number of papers published increases by 3.3% p.a. Two trends are highly significant: The fraction of theoretical papers has fallen by 26 pp (percentage points), while the fraction of papers using the classical method has increased by 15 pp. Economic theory predicts that such papers exaggerate, and the papers that have been analyzed by meta-analysis confirm the prediction. It is discussed if other methods have smaller problems.

1 Introduction

This paper studies the pattern in the research methods in economics by a sample of 3,415 regular papers published in the years 1997, 2002, 2007, 2012, and 2017 in 10 journals. The analysis builds on the beliefs that truth exists, but it is difficult to find, and that all the methods listed in the next paragraph have problems as discussed in Sections 2 and 4. Hereby I do not imply that all – or even most – papers have these problems, but we rarely know how serious it is when we read a paper. A key aspect of the problem is that a “perfect” study is very demanding and requires far too much space to report, especially if the paper looks for usable results. Thus, each paper is just one look at an aspect of the problem analyzed. Only when many studies using different methods reach a joint finding, we can trust that it is true.

Section 2 discusses the classification of papers by method into three main categories: (M1) Theory , with three subgroups: (M1.1) economic theory, (M1.2) statistical methods, and (M1.3) surveys. (M2) Experiments , with two subgroups: (M2.1) lab experiments and (M2.2) natural experiments. (M3) Empirics , with three subgroups: (M3.1) descriptive, (M3.2) classical empirics, and (M3.3) newer empirics. More than 90% of the papers are easy to classify, but a stochastic element enters in the classification of the rest. Thus, the study has some – hopefully random – measurement errors.

Section 3 discusses the sample of journals chosen. The choice has been limited by the following main criteria: It should be good journals below the top ten A-journals, i.e., my article covers B-journals, which are the journals where most research economists publish. It should be general interest journals, and the journals should be so different that it is likely that patterns that generalize across these journals apply to more (most?) journals. The Appendix gives some crude counts of researchers, departments, and journals. It assesses that there are about 150 B-level journals, but less than half meet the criteria, so I have selected about 15% of the possible ones. This is the most problematic element in the study. If the reader accepts my choice, the paper tells an interesting story about economic research.

All B-level journals try hard to have a serious refereeing process. If our selection is representative, the 150 journals have increased the annual number of papers published from about 7,500 in 1997 to about 14,000 papers in 2017, giving about 200,000 papers for the period. Thus, the B-level dominates our science. Our sample is about 6% for the years covered, but less than 2% of all papers published in B-journals in the period. However, it is a larger fraction of the papers in general interest journals.

It is impossible for anyone to read more than a small fraction of this flood of papers. Consequently, researchers compete for space in journals and for attention from the readers, as measured in the form of citations. It should be uncontroversial that papers that hold a clear message are easier to publish and get more citations. Thus, an element of sales promotion may enter papers in the form of exaggeration , which is a joint problem for all eight methods. This is in accordance with economic theory that predicts that rational researchers report exaggerated results; see Paldam ( 2016 , 2018 ). For empirical papers, meta-methods exist to summarize the results from many papers, notably papers using regressions. Section 4.4 reports that meta-studies find that exaggeration is common.

The empirical literature surveying the use of research methods is quite small, as I have found two articles only: Hamermesh ( 2013 ) covers 748 articles in 6 years a decade apart studies in three A-journals using a slightly different classification of methods, [1] while my study covers B-journals. Angrist, Azoulay, Ellison, Hill, and Lu ( 2017 ) use a machine-learning classification of 134,000 papers in 80 journals to look at the three main methods. My study subdivide the three categories into eight. The machine-learning algorithm is only sketched, so the paper is difficult to replicate, but it is surely a major effort. A key result in both articles is the strong decrease of theory in economic publications. This finding is confirmed, and it is shown that the corresponding increase in empirical articles is concentrated on the classical method.

I have tried to explain what I have done, so that everything is easy to replicate, in full or for one journal or one year. The coding of each article is available at least for the next five years. I should add that I have been in economic research for half a century. Some of the assessments in the paper will reflect my observations/experience during this period (indicated as my assessments). This especially applies to the judgements expressed in Section 4.

2 The eight categories

Table 1 reports that the annual number of papers in the ten journals has increased 1.9 times, or by 3.3% per year. The Appendix gives the full counts per category, journal, and year. By looking at data over two decades, I study how economic research develops. The increase in the production of papers is caused by two factors: The increase in the number of researchers. The increasing importance of publications for the careers of researchers.

The 3,415 papers

Year Papers Fraction Annual increase
From To In%
1997 464 13.6 1997 2002 2.2
2002 518 15.2 2002 2007 4.0
2007 661 19.4 2007 2012 4.6
2012 881 25.8 2012 2017 0.2
2017 891 26.1
Sum 3,415 100 1997 2017 3.3

2.1 (M1) Theory: subgroups (M1.1) to (M1.3)

Table 2 lists the groups and main numbers discussed in the rest of the paper. Section 2.1 discusses (M1) theory. Section 2.2 covers (M2) experimental methods, while Section 2.3 looks at (M3) empirical methods using statistical inference from data.

The 3,415 papers – fractions in percent

Three main groups Fraction Eight subgroups Fraction
(M1) Theory 49.6 (M1.1) Economic theory 45.2
(M1.2) Statistical technique, incl. forecasting 2.5
(M1.3) Surveys, incl. meta-studies 2.0
(M2) Experimental 6.4 (M2.1) Experiments in laboratories 5.7
(M2.2) Events, incl. real life experiments 0.7
(M3) Data inference 43.7 (M3.1) Descriptive, deductions from data 10.7
(M3.2) Classical empirical studies 28.5
(M3.3) Newer techniques 4.5

The change of the fractions from 1997 to 2017 in percentage points

Three main groups Change Eight subgroups Change
(M1) Theory −24.7 (M1.1) Economic theory −25.9
(M1.2) Statistical technique, incl. forecasting 2.2
(M1.3) Surveys, incl. meta-studies −1.0
(M2) Experimental 9.0 (M2.1) Experiments in laboratories 7.7
(M2.2) Events, incl. real life experiments 1.3
(M3) Data inference 15.8 (M3.1) Descriptive, deductions from data 2.4
(M3.2) Classical empirical studies 15.0
(M3.3) Newer techniques −1.7

Note: Section 3.4 tests if the pattern observed in Table 3 is statistically significant. The Appendix reports the full data.

2.1.1 (M1.1) Economic theory

Papers are where the main content is the development of a theoretical model. The ideal theory paper presents a (simple) new model that recasts the way we look at something important. Such papers are rare and obtain large numbers of citations. Most theoretical papers present variants of known models and obtain few citations.

In a few papers, the analysis is verbal, but more than 95% rely on mathematics, though the technical level differs. Theory papers may start by a descriptive introduction giving the stylized fact the model explains, but the bulk of the paper is the formal analysis, building a model and deriving proofs of some propositions from the model. It is often demonstrated how the model works by a set of simulations, including a calibration made to look realistic. However, the calibrations differ greatly by the efforts made to reach realism. Often, the simulations are in lieu of an analytical solution or just an illustration suggesting the magnitudes of the results reached.

Theoretical papers suffer from the problem known as T-hacking , [2] where the able author by a careful selection of assumptions can tailor the theory to give the results desired. Thus, the proofs made from the model may represent the ability and preferences of the researcher rather than the properties of the economy.

2.1.2 (M1.2) Statistical method

Papers reporting new estimators and tests are published in a handful of specialized journals in econometrics and mathematical statistics – such journals are not included. In our general interest journals, some papers compare estimators on actual data sets. If the demonstration of a methodological improvement is the main feature of the paper, it belongs to (M1.2), but if the economic interpretation is the main point of the paper, it belongs to (M3.2) or (M3.3). [3]

Some papers, including a special issue of Empirical Economics (vol. 53–1), deal with forecasting models. Such models normally have a weak relation to economic theory. They are sometimes justified precisely because of their eclectic nature. They are classified as either (M1.2) or (M3.1), depending upon the focus. It appears that different methods work better on different data sets, and perhaps a trade-off exists between the user-friendliness of the model and the improvement reached.

2.1.3 (M1.3) Surveys

When the literature in a certain field becomes substantial, it normally presents a motley picture with an amazing variation, especially when different schools exist in the field. Thus, a survey is needed, and our sample contains 68 survey articles. They are of two types, where the second type is still rare:

2.1.3.1 (M1.3.1) Assessed surveys

Here, the author reads the papers and assesses what the most reliable results are. Such assessments require judgement that is often quite difficult to distinguish from priors, even for the author of the survey.

2.1.3.2 (M1.3.2) Meta-studies

They are quantitative surveys of estimates of parameters claimed to be the same. Over the two decades from 1997 to 2017, about 500 meta-studies have been made in economics. Our sample includes five, which is 0.15%. [4] Meta-analysis has two levels: The basic level collects and codes the estimates and studies their distribution. This is a rather objective exercise where results seem to replicate rather well. [5] The second level analyzes the variation between the results. This is less objective. The papers analyzed by meta-studies are empirical studies using method (M3.2), though a few use estimates from (M3.1) and (M3.3).

2.2 (M2) Experimental methods: subgroups (M2.1) and (M2.2)

Experiments are of three distinct types, where the last two are rare, so they are lumped together. They are taking place in real life.

2.2.1 (M2.1) Lab experiments

The sample had 1.9% papers using this method in 1997, and it has expanded to 9.7% in 2017. It is a technique that is much easier to apply to micro- than to macroeconomics, so it has spread unequally in the 10 journals, and many experiments are reported in a couple of special journals that are not included in our sample.

Most of these experiments take place in a laboratory, where the subjects communicate with a computer, giving a controlled, but artificial, environment. [6] A number of subjects are told a (more or less abstract) story and paid to react in either of a number of possible ways. A great deal of ingenuity has gone into the construction of such experiments and in the methods used to analyze the results. Lab experiments do allow studies of behavior that are hard to analyze in any other way, and they frequently show sides of human behavior that are difficult to rationalize by economic theory. It appears that such demonstration is a strong argument for the publication of a study.

However, everything is artificial – even the payment. In some cases, the stories told are so elaborate and abstract that framing must be a substantial risk; [7] see Levitt and List ( 2007 ) for a lucid summary, and Bergh and Wichardt ( 2018 ) for a striking example. In addition, experiments cost money, which limits the number of subjects. It is also worth pointing to the difference between expressive and real behavior. It is typically much cheaper for the subject to “express” nice behavior in a lab than to be nice in the real world.

(M2.2) Event studies are studies of real world experiments. They are of two types:

(M2.2.1) Field experiments analyze cases where some people get a certain treatment and others do not. The “gold standard” for such experiments is double blind random sampling, where everything (but the result!) is preannounced; see Christensen and Miguel ( 2018 ). Experiments with humans require permission from the relevant authorities, and the experiment takes time too. In the process, things may happen that compromise the strict rules of the standard. [8] Controlled experiments are expensive, as they require a team of researchers. Our sample of papers contains no study that fulfills the gold standard requirements, but there are a few less stringent studies of real life experiments.

(M2.2.2) Natural experiments take advantage of a discontinuity in the environment, i.e., the period before and after an (unpredicted) change of a law, an earthquake, etc. Methods have been developed to find the effect of the discontinuity. Often, such studies look like (M3.2) classical studies with many controls that may or may not belong. Thus, the problems discussed under (M3.2) will also apply.

2.3 (M3) Empirical methods: subgroups (M3.1) to (M3.3)

The remaining methods are studies making inference from “real” data, which are data samples where the researcher chooses the sample, but has no control over the data generating process.

(M3.1) Descriptive studies are deductive. The researcher describes the data aiming at finding structures that tell a story, which can be interpreted. The findings may call for a formal test. If one clean test follows from the description, [9] the paper is classified under (M3.1). If a more elaborate regression analysis is used, it is classified as (M3.2). Descriptive studies often contain a great deal of theory.

Some descriptive studies present a new data set developed by the author to analyze a debated issue. In these cases, it is often possible to make a clean test, so to the extent that biases sneak in, they are hidden in the details of the assessments made when the data are compiled.

(M3.2) Classical empirics has three steps: It starts by a theory, which is developed into an operational model. Then it presents the data set, and finally it runs regressions.

The significance levels of the t -ratios on the coefficient estimated assume that the regression is the first meeting of the estimation model and the data. We all know that this is rarely the case; see also point (m1) in Section 4.4. In practice, the classical method is often just a presentation technique. The great virtue of the method is that it can be applied to real problems outside academia. The relevance comes with a price: The method is quite flexible as many choices have to be made, and they often give different results. Preferences and interests, as discussed in Sections 4.3 and 4.4 below, notably as point (m2), may affect these choices.

(M3.3) Newer empirics . Partly as a reaction to the problems of (M3.2), the last 3–4 decades have seen a whole set of newer empirical techniques. [10] They include different types of VARs, Bayesian techniques, causality/co-integration tests, Kalman Filters, hazard functions, etc. I have found 162 (or 4.7%) papers where these techniques are the main ones used. The fraction was highest in 1997. Since then it has varied, but with no trend.

I think that the main reason for the lack of success for the new empirics is that it is quite bulky to report a careful set of co-integration tests or VARs, and they often show results that are far from useful in the sense that they are unclear and difficult to interpret. With some introduction and discussion, there is not much space left in the article. Therefore, we are dealing with a cookbook that makes for rather dull dishes, which are difficult to sell in the market.

Note the contrast between (M3.2) and (M3.3): (M3.2) makes it possible to write papers that are too good, while (M3.3) often makes them too dull. This contributes to explain why (M3.2) is getting (even) more popular and the lack of success of (M3.3), but then, it is arguable that it is more dangerous to act on exaggerated results than on results that are weak.

3 The 10 journals

The 10 journals chosen are: (J1) Can [Canadian Journal of Economics], (J2) Emp [Empirical Economics], (J3) EER [European Economic Review], (J4) EJPE [European Journal of Political Economy], (J5) JEBO [Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization], (J6) Inter [Journal of International Economics], (J7) Macro [Journal of Macroeconomics], (J8) Kyklos, (J9) PuCh [Public Choice], and (J10) SJE [Scandinavian Journal of Economics].

Section 3.1 discusses the choice of journals, while Section 3.2 considers how journals deal with the pressure for publication. Section 3.3 shows the marked difference in publication profile of the journals, and Section 3.4 tests if the trends in methods are significant.

3.1 The selection of journals

They should be general interest journals – methodological journals are excluded. By general interest, I mean that they bring papers where an executive summary may interest policymakers and people in general. (ii) They should be journals in English (the Canadian Journal includes one paper in French), which are open to researchers from all countries, so that the majority of the authors are from outside the country of the journal. [11] (iii) They should be sufficiently different so that it is likely that patterns, which apply to these journals, tell a believable story about economic research. Note that (i) and (iii) require some compromises, as is evident in the choice of (J2), (J6), (J7), and (J8) ( Table 4 ).

The 10 journals covered

Journal Volume number Regular research papers published Growth
Code Name 1997 2002 2007 2012 2017 1997 2002 2007 2012 2017 All % p.a.
(J1) Can 30 35 40 45 50 68 43 55 66 46 278 −1.9
(J2) Emp 22 27 32–43 42–3 52–3 33 36 48 104 139 360 7.5
(J3) EER 41 46 51 56 91–100 56 91 89 106 140 482 4.7
(J4) EJPE 13 18 23 28 46–50 42 40 68 47 49 246 0.8
(J5) JEBO 32 47–9 62–4 82–4 133–44 41 85 101 207 229 663 9.0
(J6) Inter 42 56–8 71–3 86–8 104–9 45 59 66 87 93 350 3.7
(J7) Macro 19 24 29 34 51–4 44 25 51 79 65 264 2.0
(J8) Kyklos 50 55 60 65 70 21 22 30 29 24 126 0.7
(J9) PuCh 90–3 110–3 130–3 150–3 170–3 83 87 114 99 67 450 −1.1
(J10) SJE 99 104 109 114 119 31 30 39 57 39 196 1.2
All 464 518 661 881 891 3,415 3.3

Note. Growth is the average annual growth from 1997 to 2017 in the number of papers published.

Methodological journals are excluded, as they are not interesting to outsiders. However, new methods are developed to be used in general interest journals. From studies of citations, we know that useful methodological papers are highly cited. If they remain unused, we presume that it is because they are useless, though, of course, there may be a long lag.

The choice of journals may contain some subjectivity, but I think that they are sufficiently diverse so that patterns that generalize across these journals will also generalize across a broader range of good journals.

The papers included are the regular research articles. Consequently, I exclude short notes to other papers and book reviews, [12] except for a few article-long discussions of controversial books.

3.2 Creating space in journals

As mentioned in the introduction, the annual production of research papers in economics has now reached about 1,000 papers in top journals, and about 14,000 papers in the group of good journals. [13] The production has grown with 3.3% per year, and thus it has doubled the last twenty years. The hard-working researcher will read less than 100 papers a year. I know of no signs that this number is increasing. Thus, the upward trend in publication must be due to the large increase in the importance of publications for the careers of researchers, which has greatly increased the production of papers. There has also been a large increase in the number of researches, but as citations are increasingly skewed toward the top journals (see Heckman & Moktan, 2018 ), it has not increased demand for papers correspondingly. The pressures from the supply side have caused journals to look for ways to create space.

Book reviews have dropped to less than 1/3. Perhaps, it also indicates that economists read fewer books than they used to. Journals have increasingly come to use smaller fonts and larger pages, allowing more words per page. The journals from North-Holland Elsevier have managed to cram almost two old pages into one new one. [14] This makes it easier to publish papers, while they become harder to read.

Many journals have changed their numbering system for the annual issues, making it less transparent how much they publish. Only three – Canadian Economic Journal, Kyklos, and Scandinavian Journal of Economics – have kept the schedule of publishing one volume of four issues per year. It gives about 40 papers per year. Public Choice has a (fairly) consistent system with four volumes of two double issues per year – this gives about 100 papers. The remaining journals have changed their numbering system and increased the number of papers published per year – often dramatically.

Thus, I assess the wave of publications is caused by the increased supply of papers and not to the demand for reading material. Consequently, the study confirms and updates the observation by Temple ( 1918 , p. 242): “… as the world gets older the more people are inclined to write but the less they are inclined to read.”

3.3 How different are the journals?

The appendix reports the counts for each year and journal of the research methods. From these counts, a set of χ 2 -scores is calculated for the three main groups of methods – they are reported in Table 5 . It gives the χ 2 -test comparing the profile of each journal to the one of the other nine journals taken to be the theoretical distribution.

The methodological profile of the journals –  χ 2 -scores for main groups

Journal (M1) (M2) (M3) Sum -value
Code Name Theory Experiment Empirical (3)-test (%)
(J1) Can 7.4(+) 15.3(−) 1.7(−) 24.4 0.00
(J2) Emp 47.4(−) 16.0(−) 89.5(+) 152.9 0.00
(J3) EER 17.8(+) 0.3(−) 16.5(−) 34.4 0.00
(J4) EJPE 0.1(+) 11.2(−) 1.0(+) 12.2 0.31
(J5) JEBO 1.6(−) 1357.7(+) 41.1(−) 1404.4 0.00
(J6) Inter 2.4(+) 24.8(−) 0.1(+) 27.3 0.00
(J7) Macro 0.1(+) 18.2(−) 1.7(+) 20.0 0.01
(J8) Kyklos 20.1(−) 3.3(−) 31.2(+) 54.6 0.00
(J9) PuCh 0.0(+) 11.7(−) 2.2(+) 13.9 0.14
(J10) SJE 10.5(+) 1.8(−) 8.2(−) 20.4 0.01

Note: The χ 2 -scores are calculated relative to all other journals. The sign (+) or (−) indicates if the journal has too many or too few papers relatively in the category. The P -values for the χ 2 (3)-test always reject that the journal has the same methodological profile as the other nine journals.

The test rejects that the distribution is the same as the average for any of the journals. The closest to the average is the EJPE and Public Choice. The two most deviating scores are for the most micro-oriented journal JEBO, which brings many experimental papers, and of course, Empirical Economics, which brings many empirical papers.

3.4 Trends in the use of the methods

Table 3 already gave an impression of the main trends in the methods preferred by economists. I now test if these impressions are statistically significant. The tests have to be tailored to disregard three differences between the journals: their methodological profiles, the number of papers they publish, and the trend in the number. Table 6 reports a set of distribution free tests, which overcome these differences. The tests are done on the shares of each research method for each journal. As the data cover five years, it gives 10 pairs of years to compare. [15] The three trend-scores in the []-brackets count how often the shares go up, down, or stay the same in the 10 cases. This is the count done for a Kendall rank correlation comparing the five shares with a positive trend (such as 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5).

Trend-scores and tests for the eight subgroups of methods across the 10 journals

Journal (M1.1) (M1.2) (M1.3) (M2.1) (M2.2) (M3.1) (M3.2) (M3.3)
Code Name Theory Stat met Survey Exp. Event Descript. Classical Newer
(J1) Can [6, 3, 1] [6, 3, 1] [3, 1, 6] [3, 1, 6] [6, 4, 0] [8, 2, 0] [5, 4, 1]
(J2) Emp [2, 8, 0] [6, 4, 0] [0, 7, 3] [0, 4, 6] [3, 4, 3] [6, 4, 0] [8, 2, 0] [4, 6, 0]
(J3) EER [3, 7, 0] [4, 0, 6] [3, 1, 6] [7, 3, 0] [8, 2, 0] [3, 7, 0]
(J4) EJPE [0, 0, 10] [4, 0, 6] [4, 0, 6] [4, 6, 0] [8, 1, 0]
(J5) JEBO [2, 8, 0] [6, 1, 3] [6, 3, 1] [7, 3, 0] [6, 1, 3] [4, 6, 0] [8, 2, 0] [2, 4, 3]
(J6) Inter [0, 0, 10] [0, 0, 10] [0, 0, 10] [0, 0, 10] [8, 2, 0] [8, 2, 0] [4, 6, 0]
(J7) Macro [6, 4, 0] [5, 5, 0] [7, 2, 1] [0, 0, 10] [0, 0, 10] [3, 7, 0]
(J8) Kyklos [2, 8, 0] [0, 0, 10] [2, 2, 6] [2, 7, 1] [0, 0, 10] [4, 6, 0] [2, 2, 6]
(J9) PuCh [3, 7, 0] [4, 3, 3] [6, 3, 1] [4, 3, 3] [0, 0, 10] [5, 5, 0] [6, 4, 0] [6, 3, 1]
(J10) SJE [4, 0, 6] [6, 3, 1] [1, 3, 6] [3, 1, 6] [6, 4, 0] [6, 4, 0] [6, 1, 1]
All 100 per col. [22, 78, 0] [35, 16, 49] [35, 41, 24] [30, 22, 48] [22, 8, 70] [59, 41, 0] [73, 27, 0] [42, 43, 13]
Binominal test 56% 33% 8.86% 100%

Note: The three trend-scores in each [ I 1 , I 2 , I 3 ]-bracket are a Kendall-count over all 10 combinations of years. I 1 counts how often the share goes up. I 2 counts when the share goes down, and I 3 counts the number of ties. Most ties occur when there are no observations either year. Thus, I 1 + I 2 + I 3 = 10. The tests are two-sided binominal tests disregarding the zeroes. The test results in bold are significant at the 5% level.

The first set of trend-scores for (M1.1) and (J1) is [1, 9, 0]. It means that 1 of the 10 share-pairs increases, while nine decrease and no ties are found. The two-sided binominal test is 2%, so it is unlikely to happen. Nine of the ten journals in the (M1.1)-column have a majority of falling shares. The important point is that the counts in one column can be added – as is done in the all-row; this gives a powerful trend test that disregards differences between journals and the number of papers published. ( Table A1 )

Four of the trend-tests are significant: The fall in theoretical papers and the rise in classical papers. There is also a rise in the share of stat method and event studies. It is surprising that there is no trend in the number of experimental studies, but see Table A2 (in Appendix).

4 An attempt to interpret the pattern found

The development in the methods pursued by researchers in economics is a reaction to the demand and supply forces on the market for economic papers. As already argued, it seems that a key factor is the increasing production of papers.

The shares add to 100, so the decline of one method means that the others rise. Section 4.1 looks at the biggest change – the reduction in theory papers. Section 4.2 discusses the rise in two new categories. Section 4.3 considers the large increase in the classical method, while Section 4.4 looks at what we know about that method from meta-analysis.

4.1 The decline of theory: economics suffers from theory fatigue [16]

The papers in economic theory have dropped from 59.5 to 33.6% – this is the largest change for any of the eight subgroups. [17] It is highly significant in the trend test. I attribute this drop to theory fatigue.

As mentioned in Section 2.1, the ideal theory paper presents a (simple) new model that recasts the way we look at something important. However, most theory papers are less exciting: They start from the standard model and argue that a well-known conclusion reached from the model hinges upon a debatable assumption – if it changes, so does the conclusion. Such papers are useful. From a literature on one main model, the profession learns its strengths and weaknesses. It appears that no generally accepted method exists to summarize this knowledge in a systematic way, though many thoughtful summaries have appeared.

I think that there is a deeper problem explaining theory fatigue. It is that many theoretical papers are quite unconvincing. Granted that the calculations are done right, believability hinges on the realism of the assumptions at the start and of the results presented at the end. In order for a model to convince, it should (at least) demonstrate the realism of either the assumptions or the outcome. [18] If both ends appear to hang in the air, it becomes a game giving little new knowledge about the world, however skillfully played.

The theory fatigue has caused a demand for simulations demonstrating that the models can mimic something in the world. Kydland and Prescott pioneered calibration methods (see their 1991 ). Calibrations may be carefully done, but it often appears like a numerical solution of a model that is too complex to allow an analytical solution.

4.2 Two examples of waves: one that is still rising and another that is fizzling out

When a new method of gaining insights in the economy first appears, it is surrounded by doubts, but it also promises a high marginal productivity of knowledge. Gradually the doubts subside, and many researchers enter the field. After some time this will cause the marginal productivity of the method to fall, and it becomes less interesting. The eight methods include two newer ones: Lab experiments and newer stats. [19]

It is not surprising that papers with lab experiments are increasing, though it did take a long time: The seminal paper presenting the technique was Smith ( 1962 ), but only a handful of papers are from the 1960s. Charles Plott organized the first experimental lab 10 years later – this created a new standard for experiments, but required an investment in a lab and some staff. Labs became more common in the 1990s as PCs got cheaper and software was developed to handle experiments, but only 1.9% of the papers in the 10 journals reported lab experiments in 1997. This has now increased to 9.7%, so the wave is still rising. The trend in experiments is concentrated in a few journals, so the trend test in Table 6 is insignificant, but it is significant in the Appendix Table A2 , where it is done on the sum of articles irrespective of the journal.

In addition to the rising share of lab experiment papers in some journals, the journal Experimental Economics was started in 1998, where it published 281 pages in three issues. In 2017, it had reached 1,006 pages in four issues, [20] which is an annual increase of 6.5%.

Compared with the success of experimental economics, the motley category of newer empirics has had a more modest success, as the fraction of papers in the 5 years are 5.8, 5.2, 3.5, 5.4, and 4.2, which has no trend. Newer stats also require investment, but mainly in human capital. [21] Some of the papers using the classical methodology contain a table with Dickey-Fuller tests or some eigenvalues of the data matrix, but they are normally peripheral to the analysis. A couple of papers use Kalman filters, and a dozen papers use Bayesian VARs. However, it is clear that the newer empirics have made little headway into our sample of general interest journals.

4.3 The steady rise of the classical method: flexibility rewarded

The typical classical paper provides estimates of a key effect that decision-makers outside academia want to know. This makes the paper policy relevant right from the start, and in many cases, it is possible to write a one page executive summary to the said decision-makers.

The three-step convention (see Section 2.3) is often followed rather loosely. The estimation model is nearly always much simpler than the theory. Thus, while the model can be derived from a theory, the reverse does not apply. Sometimes, the model seems to follow straight from common sense, and if the link from the theory to the model is thin, it begs the question: Is the theory really necessary? In such cases, it is hard to be convinced that the tests “confirm” the theory, but then, of course, tests only say that the data do not reject the theory.

The classical method is often only a presentation devise. Think of a researcher who has reached a nice publishable result through a long and tortuous path, including some failed attempts to find such results. It is not possible to describe that path within the severely limited space of an article. In addition, such a presentation would be rather dull to read, and none of us likes to talk about wasted efforts that in hindsight seem a bit silly. Here, the classical method becomes a convenient presentation device.

The biggest source of variation in the results is the choice of control/modifier variables. All datasets presumably contain some general and some special information, where the latter depends on the circumstances prevailing when the data were compiled. The regression should be controlled for these circumstances in order to reach the general result. Such ceteris paribus controls are not part of the theory, so many possible controls may be added. The ones chosen for publication often appear to be the ones delivering the “right” results by the priors of the researcher. The justification for their inclusion is often thin, and if two-stage regressions are used, the first stage instruments often have an even thinner justification.

Thus, the classical method is rather malleable to the preferences and interests of researchers and sponsors. This means that some papers using the classical technique are not what they pretend, as already pointed out by Leamer ( 1983 ), see also Paldam ( 2018 ) for new references and theory. The fact that data mining is tempting suggests that it is often possible to reach smashing results, making the paper nice to read. This may be precisely why it is cited.

Many papers using the classical method throw in some bits of exotic statistics technique to demonstrate the robustness of the result and the ability of the researcher. This presumably helps to generate credibility.

4.4 Knowledge about classical papers reached from meta-studies

(m1) The range of the estimates is typically amazingly large, given the high -ratios reported. This confirms that -ratios are problematic as claimed in Section 2.3.
(m2) Publication biases (exaggerations) are common, i.e., meta-analyses routinely reject the null hypothesis of no publication bias. My own crude rule of thumb is that exaggeration is by a factor two – the two meta–meta studies cited give some support to this rule.
(m3) The meta-average estimated from all studies normally converges, and for > 30, the meta-average normally stabilizes to a well-defined value, see Doucouliagos et al. ( ).

Individual studies using the classical method often look better than they are, and thus they are more uncertain than they appear, but we may think of the value of convergence for large N s (number of observations) as the truth. The exaggeration is largest in the beginning of a new literature, but gradually it becomes smaller. Thus, the classical method does generate truth when the effect searched for has been studied from many sides. The word research does mean that the search has to be repeated! It is highly risky to trust a few papers only.

Meta-analysis has found other results such as: Results in top journals do not stand out. It is necessary to look at many journals, as many papers on the same effect are needed. Little of the large variation between results is due to the choice of estimators.

A similar development should occur also for experimental economics. Experiments fall in families: A large number cover prisoner’s dilemma games, but there are also many studies of dictator games, auction games, etc. Surveys summarizing what we have learned about these games seem highly needed. Assessed summaries of old experiments are common, notably in introductions to papers reporting new ones. It should be possible to extract the knowledge reached by sets of related lab experiments in a quantitative way, by some sort of meta-technique, but this has barely started. The first pioneering meta-studies of lab experiments do find the usual wide variation of results from seemingly closely related experiments. [25] A recent large-scale replicability study by Camerer et al. ( 2018 ) finds that published experiments in the high quality journal Nature and Science exaggerate by a factor two just like regression studies using the classical method.

5 Conclusion

The study presents evidence that over the last 20 years economic research has moved away from theory towards empirical work using the classical method.

From the eighties onward, there has been a steady stream of papers pointing out that the classical method suffers from excess flexibility. It does deliver relevant results, but they tend to be too good. [26] While, increasingly, we know the size of the problems of the classical method, systematic knowledge about the problems of the other methods is weaker. It is possible that the problems are smaller, but we do not know.

Therefore, it is clear that obtaining solid knowledge about the size of an important effect requires a great deal of papers analyzing many aspects of the effect and a careful quantitative survey. It is a well-known principle in the harder sciences that results need repeated independent replication to be truly trustworthy. In economics, this is only accepted in principle.

The classical method of empirical research is gradually winning, and this is a fine development: It does give answers to important policy questions. These answers are highly variable and often exaggerated, but through the efforts of many competing researchers, solid knowledge will gradually emerge.

Home page: http://www.martin.paldam.dk

Acknowledgments

The paper has been presented at the 2018 MAER-Net Colloquium in Melbourne, the Kiel Aarhus workshop in 2018, and at the European Public Choice 2019 Meeting in Jerusalem. I am grateful for all comments, especially from Chris Doucouliagos, Eelke de Jong, and Bob Reed. In addition, I thank the referees for constructive advice.

Conflict of interest: Author states no conflict of interest.

Appendix: Two tables and some assessments of the size of the profession

The text needs some numbers to assess the representativity of the results reached. These numbers just need to be orders of magnitude. I use the standard three-level classification in A, B, and C of researchers, departments, and journals. The connections between the three categories are dynamic and rely on complex sorting mechanisms. In an international setting, it matters that researchers have preferences for countries, notably their own. The relation between the three categories has a stochastic element.

The World of Learning organization reports on 36,000 universities, colleges, and other institutes of tertiary education and research. Many of these institutions are mainly engaged in undergraduate teaching, and some are quite modest. If half of these institutions have a program in economics, with a staff of at least five, the total stock of academic economists is 100,000, of which most are at the C-level.

The A-level of about 500 tenured researchers working at the top ten universities (mainly) publishes in the top 10 journals that bring less than 1,000 papers per year; [27] see Heckman and Moktan (2020). They (mainly) cite each other, but they greatly influence other researchers. [28] The B-level consists of about 15–20,000 researchers who work at 4–500 research universities, with graduate programs and ambitions to publish. They (mainly) publish in the next level of about 150 journals. [29] In addition, there are at least another 1,000 institutions that strive to move up in the hierarchy.

The counts for each of the 10 journals

Main group (M1) (M2) (M3)
Subgroup (M1.1) (M1.2) (M1.3) (M2.1) (M2.2) (M3.1) (M3.2) (M3.3)
Number papers Theory Stat. theory Surveys meta Experiments Event studies Descriptive Classical empiric Newer empiric
(J1) Can 68 47 2 10 8 1
(J2) Emp 33 11 5 1 7 3 6
(J3) EER 56 34 3 4 12 3
(J4) EJPE 42 29 2 5 6
(J5) JEBO 41 26 7 3 5
(J6) Inter 45 35 1 7 2
(J7) Macro 44 18 1 10 15
(J8) Kyklos 21 10 1 4 6
(J9) PuCh 83 40 7 1 1 8 26
(J10) SJE 31 26 1 4
(J1) Can 43 27 1 5 7 3
(J2) Emp 36 1 14 1 4 7 9
(J3) EER 91 63 4 3 4 17
(J4) EJPE 40 27 2 2 9
(J5) JEBO 85 52 3 14 10 5 1
(J6) Inter 59 40 4 9 6
(J7) Macro 25 8 2 1 6 8
(J8) Kyklos 22 6 1 2 13
(J9) PuCh 87 39 2 1 14 31
(J10) SJE 30 18 2 10
(J1) Can 55 26 4 6 17 2
(J2) Emp 48 4 8 3 23 10
(J3) EER 89 55 2 1 8 20 3
(J4) EJPE 68 36 2 9 20 1
(J5) JEBO 101 73 10 3 3 12
(J6) Inter 66 39 4 21 2
(J7) Macro 51 30 1 6 10 4
(J8) Kyklos 30 2 1 6 20 1
(J9) PuCh 114 53 4 19 38
(J10) SJE 39 29 1 1 2 6
(J1) Can 66 33 1 1 1 8 21 1
(J2) Emp 104 8 16 17 38 25
(J3) EER 106 56 7 1 7 33 2
(J4) EJPE 47 12 1 2 31 1
(J5) JEBO 207 75 2 9 50 17 52 2
(J6) Inter 87 36 17 33 1
(J7) Macro 79 32 2 3 12 14 16
(J8) Kyklos 29 8 2 19
(J9) PuCh 99 47 2 2 48
(J10) SJE 57 32 2 1 22
(J1) Can 46 20 1 5 9 9 2
(J2) Emp 139 1 25 4 30 60 19
(J3) EER 140 75 1 1 16 13 32 2
(J4) EJPE 49 14 2 1 4 27 1
(J5) JEBO 229 66 1 3 63 9 11 76
(J6) Inter 93 42 10 33 8
(J7) Macro 65 28 1 9 10 13 4
(J8) Kyklos 24 1 1 3 19
(J9) PuCh 67 33 1 3 10 20
(J10) SJE 39 19 1 1 1 4 12 1

Counts, shares, and changes for all ten journals for subgroups

Number (M1.1) (M1.2) (M1.3) (M2.1) (M2.2) (M3.1) (M3.2) (M3.3)
Year I: Sum of counts
1997 464 276 5 15 9 2 43 87 27
2002 518 281 19 11 21 0 45 114 27
2007 661 347 10 9 15 4 66 187 23
2012 881 339 21 13 62 3 106 289 48
2017 891 299 29 20 86 15 104 301 37
All years 3,415 1,542 84 68 193 24 364 978 162
Year II: Average fraction in per cent
1997 100 59.5 1.1 3.2 1.9 0.4 9.3 18.8 5.8
2002 100 54.2 3.7 2.1 4.1 8.7 22.0 5.2
2007 100 52.5 1.5 1.4 2.3 0.6 10.0 28.3 3.5
2012 100 38.5 2.4 1.5 7.0 0.3 12.0 32.8 5.4
2017 100 33.6 3.3 2.2 9.7 1.7 11.7 33.8 4.2
All years 100 45.2 2.5 2.0 5.7 0.7 10.7 28.6 4.7
Trends-scores [0, 10, 0] [7, 3, 0] [4, 6, 0] [9, 1, 0] [5, 5, 0] [8, 2, 0] [10, 0, 0] [3, 7, 0]
Binominal test 34 37 100 11 34
From To III: Change of fraction in percentage points
1997 2002 −5.2 2.6 −1.1 2.1 −0.4 −0.6 3.3 −0.6
2002 2007 −1.8 −2.2 −0.8 −1.8 0.6 1.3 6.3 −1.7
2007 2012 −14.0 0.9 0.1 4.8 −0.3 2.0 4.5 2.0
2012 2017 −4.9 0.9 0.8 2.6 1.3 −0.4 1.0 −1.3
1997 2017 −25.9 2.2 −1.0 7.7 1.3 2.4 15.0 −1.7

Note: The trend-scores are calculated as in Table 6 . Compared to the results in Table 6 , the results are similar, but the power is less than before. However, note that the results in Column (M2.1) dealing with experiments are stronger in Table A2 . This has to do with the way missing observations are treated in the test.

Angrist, J. , Azoulay, P. , Ellison, G. , Hill, R. , & Lu, S. F. (2017). Economic research evolves: Fields and styles. American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 107, 293–297. 10.1257/aer.p20171117 Search in Google Scholar

Bergh, A. , & Wichardt, P. C. (2018). Mine, ours or yours? Unintended framing effects in dictator games (INF Working Papers, No 1205). Research Institute of Industrial Econ, Stockholm. München: CESifo. 10.2139/ssrn.3208589 Search in Google Scholar

Brodeur, A. , Cook, N. , & Heyes, A. (2020). Methods matter: p-Hacking and publication bias in causal analysis in economics. American Economic Review, 110(11), 3634–3660. 10.1257/aer.20190687 Search in Google Scholar

Camerer, C. F. , Dreber, A. , Holzmaster, F. , Ho, T.-H. , Huber, J. , Johannesson, M. , … Wu, H. (27 August 2018). Nature Human Behaviour. https://www.nature.com/articles/M2.11562-018-0399-z Search in Google Scholar

Card, D. , & DellaVigna, A. (2013). Nine facts about top journals in economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 51, 144–161 10.3386/w18665 Search in Google Scholar

Christensen, G. , & Miguel, E. (2018). Transparency, reproducibility, and the credibility of economics research. Journal of Economic Literature, 56, 920–980 10.3386/w22989 Search in Google Scholar

Doucouliagos, H. , Paldam, M. , & Stanley, T. D. (2018). Skating on thin evidence: Implications for public policy. European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 16–25 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.03.004 Search in Google Scholar

Engel, C. (2011). Dictator games: A meta study. Experimental Economics, 14, 583–610 10.1007/s10683-011-9283-7 Search in Google Scholar

Fiala, L. , & Suentes, S. (2017). Transparency and cooperation in repeated dilemma games: A meta study. Experimental Economics, 20, 755–771 10.1007/s10683-017-9517-4 Search in Google Scholar

Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Search in Google Scholar

Hamermesh, D. (2013). Six decades of top economics publishing: Who and how? Journal of Economic Literature, 51, 162–172 10.3386/w18635 Search in Google Scholar

Heckman, J. J. , & Moktan, S. (2018). Publishing and promotion in economics: The tyranny of the top five. Journal of Economic Literature, 51, 419–470 10.3386/w25093 Search in Google Scholar

Ioannidis, J. P. A. , Stanley, T. D. , & Doucouliagos, H. (2017). The power of bias in economics research. Economic Journal, 127, F236–F265 10.1111/ecoj.12461 Search in Google Scholar

Johansen, S. , & Juselius, K. (1990). Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration – with application to the demand for money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, 169–210 10.1111/j.1468-0084.1990.mp52002003.x Search in Google Scholar

Justman, M. (2018). Randomized controlled trials informing public policy: Lessons from the project STAR and class size reduction. European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 167–174 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.04.005 Search in Google Scholar

Kydland, F. , & Prescott, E. C. (1991). The econometrics of the general equilibrium approach to business cycles. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 93, 161–178 10.2307/3440324 Search in Google Scholar

Leamer, E. E. (1983). Let’s take the con out of econometrics. American Economic Review, 73, 31–43 Search in Google Scholar

Levitt, S. D. , & List, J. A. (2007). On the generalizability of lab behaviour to the field. Canadian Journal of Economics, 40, 347–370 10.1111/j.1365-2966.2007.00412.x Search in Google Scholar

Paldam, M. (April 14th 2015). Meta-analysis in a nutshell: Techniques and general findings. Economics. The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 9, 1–4 10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2015-11 Search in Google Scholar

Paldam, M. (2016). Simulating an empirical paper by the rational economist. Empirical Economics, 50, 1383–1407 10.1007/s00181-015-0971-6 Search in Google Scholar

Paldam, M. (2018). A model of the representative economist, as researcher and policy advisor. European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 6–15 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.03.005 Search in Google Scholar

Smith, V. (1962). An experimental study of competitive market behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 111–137 10.1017/CBO9780511528354.003 Search in Google Scholar

Stanley, T. D. , & Doucouliagos, H. (2012). Meta-regression analysis in economics and business. Abingdon: Routledge. 10.4324/9780203111710 Search in Google Scholar

Temple, C. L. (1918). Native races and their rulers; sketches and studies of official life and administrative problems in Nigeria. Cape Town: Argus Search in Google Scholar

© 2021 Martin Paldam, published by De Gruyter

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

  • X / Twitter

Supplementary Materials

  • Supplementary material

Please login or register with De Gruyter to order this product.

Economics

Journal and Issue

Articles in the same issue.

research studies about economics

About the NBER

Information on affiliates, working papers, subscribers, graph

The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) is a private, nonprofit organization that facilitates cutting-edge research on and analysis of major economic issues. It is nonpartisan and refrains from making policy recommendations, focusing instead on providing background studies and data that underlie decision-making in both the public and private sectors. 

Founded in New York City in 1920 and today headquartered in Cambridge, Massachusetts, the NBER is a network of more than 1,800 academic economists . These researchers are leaders in the field: 44 current or former NBER affiliates have been awarded the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences, and 13 have chaired the President’s Council of Economic Advisers. 

The NBER is best known for its working paper series , which includes roughly 1,200 papers each year, and for the work of its Business Cycle Dating Committee , which identifies peaks and troughs in economic activity in the United States.

Organizational Structure

NBER affiliates are organized into 19 research programs that focus on advancing research in particular subfields of economics, such as monetary economics, labor economics, or international trade. Each is led by one or two directors. Affiliates in each program meet several times a year to share and discuss their latest findings. These meetings provide a critical venue for assessing research findings and framing the research agenda.   

The NBER supports economic research by administering affiliates’ research grants by convening  research projects and conferences  on emerging economic issues, disseminating research findings, maintaining an archive of  datasets  that are used in economic research, and supporting early career economists.

A diverse  board of directors  includes representatives of 16 research universities, 6 professional associations related to economics, and 25 leaders from the business and labor communities. The president and chief executive officer, MIT professor of economics James Poterba , leads an administrative staff of 45.

Affiliated Researchers

NBER affiliates  contribute to the organization’s research activity and are the core participants in research meetings. Many NBER affiliates are long-serving; nominations of new affiliates are considered once each year. The review process, led by program directors and committees of other leading scholars in each field, is highly competitive. Nominees must hold primary academic affiliations at North American colleges or universities. Tenured researchers are considered for appointment as Research Associates and untenured scholars as Faculty Research Fellows. Roughly 80 percent of the NBER’s affiliated scholars are Research Associates. In recent years, about 65 new affiliates have been selected annually from a pool of more than 350 nominees.

Funding and Support

Many NBER affiliates apply to federal agencies or private foundations for research grants that are administered by the NBER. The NBER also periodically convenes teams of researchers to study particular questions. Recent projects have examined the potential economic impacts of artificial intelligence , the role of supply chain disruptions in macroeconomic policy outcomes, the contributions of entrepreneurship and innovation to economic activity, and the economics of transportation markets . 

The NBER is  supported  by grants from government agencies and private foundations, contributions from corporations and individuals, subscription revenue, and portfolio income. In recent years, the largest funders have been the National Institutes of Health, the National Science Foundation, the Social Security Administration, and the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation. Roughly 80 percent of the NBER’s annual operating budget is funded by competitive grants awarded to its affiliated researchers. Another 15 percent is funded with income from its investment portfolio and less than 5 percent from corporate and individual philanthropy. 

Communicating Research Findings

Working papers and periodicals.

The NBER Working Paper series is the primary means of circulating new research findings for discussion and comment. These papers, which have not been peer-reviewed, report both empirical and theoretical findings. Working paper authors must disclose any financial or other interests that might bear on their research, and the papers must not contain policy recommendations. Roughly 25 new papers are posted each Monday and distributed via New This Week to more than 50,000 email subscribers. More than 30,000 working papers are open access. In total, working paper abstract pages are viewed about 650,000 times every month.

Nontechnical summaries of recent working papers appear each month in  The Digest . Reports on NBER programs and summaries of affiliated researchers’ latest work are presented in the quarterly  NBER Reporter . The Digest is emailed to more than 40,000 subscribers and is visited online, on average, more than 85,000 times per month. A May 2020 Digest article, “ Social and Economic Impacts of the 1918 Influenza Epidemic ,” has been viewed more than 126,000 times. Three specialized newsletters highlight particular areas of NBER research: The Bulletin on Entrepreneurship , The Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , and The Bulletin on Health . 

In addition to showcasing the latest research, the more than 32,000 NBER Working Papers online and the more than 3,100 periodicals about them serve as an important primary-source repository of economics research since 1973. 

Conferences and Videos

The NBER convenes approximately 150 scholarly  conferences each year. The Summer Institute , a three-week gathering each July, congregates more than 3,600 researchers hailing from more than 43 countries and is organized into 51 distinct meetings. Participants represent more than 500 universities, central banks, think tanks, businesses, and government agencies.

In recent years, the capstone Summer Institute event, the Martin Feldstein Lecture , has featured Cecilia Rouse, former chair of the Council of Economic Advisers and currently president of the Brookings Institution and a professor at Princeton University; Mario Draghi, former president of the European Central Bank and former prime minister of Italy; Gita Gopinath, First Deputy Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund; and Harvard University professor Claudia Goldin, the 2023 Nobel Laureate in Economics.   

The majority of NBER conferences are accessible to the public on YouTube . Many of these live streams are edited and saved; they attracted more than 220,000 views in 2023. The NBER has archived more than 440 videos.   

Diversity and Inclusion

The NBER recognizes that diversity in a research community increases the quality of its work, the range of questions it studies, and the extent to which its findings inform a broad range of policy challenges. The NBER is therefore committed to developing diversity and inclusion among affiliated scholars and conference participants. It follows a diversity policy to further these goals.

Research Fields

Main research fields in the department. Click to see faculty working in each area. 

Applied Microeconomics

Behavioral and experimental economics, decision theory, development economics, econometrics, economic history, economics of education, economics of technology, environmental, resource and energy economics, financial economics, game theory, health economics, industrial organization, international trade, labor economics, macroeconomics, market design, microeconomic theory, monetary economics, political economy, public economics.

  • Utility Menu

University Logo

44d3fa3df9f06a3117ed3d2ad6c71ecc

  • Administration

research-banner.jpg

people standing next to pile of books

Current student and faculty research, initiatives, and resources in the department 

Find Faculty by Economic Field

research studies about economics

Behavioral Economics

research studies about economics

Industrial Organization

Political economy.

research studies about economics

Economic Development

research studies about economics

International Economics

Public economics, econometrics, labor economics, financial economics, macroeconomics, economic history, research initiatives.

Our faculty-led initiatives showcase just some of the department's vast endeavors to further our understanding of the world through the lens of economics.  Our current initiatives are listed below.

research studies about economics

Foundations of Human Behavior Initiative

The Foundations of Human Behavior Initiative (FHB) supports research that produces transformative insights about the psychological, social, economic, political, and biological mechanisms that influence human behavior.   

research studies about economics

German Administrative Data Project

The Research Data Center (FDZ) of the German Federal Employment Agency (BA) in the Institute for Employment Research (IAB) facilitates access to micro data on the labor market for non-commercial empirical research.

research studies about economics

The Lab for Economic Applications and Policy (LEAP) facilitates research related to government policy, with the aim of injecting scientific evidence into policy debates

research studies about economics

Opportunity Insights

Opportunity Insights identifies barriers to economic opportunity and develop scalable solutions that will empower people throughout the United States to rise out of poverty and achieve better life outcomes.

The Weiss Fund

The Weiss Fund for Research in Development Economics is funded by the CRI Foundation and aims to sponsor research that will positively affect the lives of poor people in poor countries. 

Robin Lee

Faculty Feature

Professor Robin Lee and his co-author, Professor Kate Ho, have just been announced as the winners of the 2020 Frisch Medal of the Econometric Society for their paper “Insurer Competition in Health Care Markets”. 

Elisa Rubbo and Jonathan Roth

Student Feature

Elisa Rubbo is awarded the Padma Desai Prize in Economics and Jonathan Roth wins the David A. Well's Prize.

Research Resources

research studies about economics

Use of Human Subjects

  • Harvard FAS Human Subject Research Site
  • Human Subject Payment Information

research studies about economics

Research Agreements / Contracts

  • Model Consulting Agreement of Harvard
  • Harvard Legal Agreements Workflow, Negotiating Authority and Signing Authority

research studies about economics

Research Travel Information

  • Travel on Sponsored Funding
  • Harvard Travel Services
  • Global Support Services

research studies about economics

Data Use Agreements

Learn more about data use agreements

Programs submenu

Regions submenu, topics submenu, japan searches for leadership, driving impact live: championing gender equality with amb. geeta rao gupta, hedging their bets: taiwan industry adapts to geostrategic risks, strategic equilibrium: america’s manufacturing resurgence and the role of natural gas in the carbon competitive world.

  • Abshire-Inamori Leadership Academy
  • Aerospace Security Project
  • Africa Program
  • Americas Program
  • Arleigh A. Burke Chair in Strategy
  • Asia Maritime Transparency Initiative
  • Asia Program
  • Australia Chair
  • Brzezinski Chair in Global Security and Geostrategy
  • Brzezinski Institute on Geostrategy
  • Chair in U.S.-India Policy Studies
  • China Power Project
  • Chinese Business and Economics
  • Defending Democratic Institutions
  • Defense-Industrial Initiatives Group
  • Defense 360
  • Defense Budget Analysis
  • Diversity and Leadership in International Affairs Project

Economics Program

  • Emeritus Chair in Strategy
  • Energy Security and Climate Change Program
  • Europe, Russia, and Eurasia Program
  • Freeman Chair in China Studies
  • Futures Lab
  • Geoeconomic Council of Advisers
  • Global Food and Water Security Program
  • Global Health Policy Center
  • Hess Center for New Frontiers
  • Human Rights Initiative
  • Humanitarian Agenda
  • Intelligence, National Security, and Technology Program
  • International Security Program
  • Japan Chair
  • Kissinger Chair
  • Korea Chair
  • Langone Chair in American Leadership
  • Middle East Program
  • Missile Defense Project
  • Project on Critical Minerals Security
  • Project on Fragility and Mobility
  • Project on Nuclear Issues
  • Project on Prosperity and Development
  • Project on Trade and Technology
  • Renewing American Innovation

Scholl Chair in International Business

  • Smart Women, Smart Power
  • Southeast Asia Program
  • Stephenson Ocean Security Project

Strategic Technologies Program

  • Sustainable Development and Resilience Initiative
  • Wadhwani Center for AI and Advanced Technologies
  • Warfare, Irregular Threats, and Terrorism Program
  • All Regions
  • Australia, New Zealand & Pacific
  • Middle East
  • Russia and Eurasia
  • American Innovation
  • Civic Education
  • Climate Change
  • Cybersecurity
  • Defense Budget and Acquisition
  • Defense and Security
  • Energy and Sustainability
  • Food Security
  • Gender and International Security
  • Geopolitics
  • Global Health
  • Human Rights
  • Humanitarian Assistance
  • Intelligence
  • International Development
  • Maritime Issues and Oceans
  • Missile Defense
  • Nuclear Issues
  • Transnational Threats
  • Water Security
  • Asian Economics
  • Global Economic Governance

CSIS’s Economics Program , the Scholl Chair in International Business , and the Strategic Technologies Program , explore the nexus between economics and national security at a time when international relations are increasingly defined by the pursuit of economic and commercial power.

Photo: Andreea Campeanu/Getty Images

Photo: Andreea Campeanu/Getty Images

Moldova’s Gas Futures

Without true energy independence from Russia, the threat of Moscow turning off the heat in Chisinau or creating a crisis in Transnistria will remain a geopolitical tool to pressure or destabilize Moldova.

Critical Questions by Daniel F. Runde, Leah Kieff, and Thomas Bryja — September 9, 2024

Photo: Costfoto/NurPhoto/Getty Images

Are the Chickens Coming Home to Roost?

Commentary by William Alan Reinsch — September 9, 2024

Photo: Scott Kennedy/CSIS

Diversifying, Not Decoupling

Report by Scott Kennedy and Andrea Leonard Palazzi — September 9, 2024

Photo: Kent Nishimura/Bloomberg via Getty Images

All Bark and No Bite? The 118th Congress on China

Blog Post by Ryan Featherston and Nancy Wei — September 6, 2024

Latest Podcasts

A tall tower stands in front of a desert.

Analysis: The Hostage Crisis in Gaza

Podcast Episode by Jon B. Alterman and Leah Hickert — September 10, 2024

Driving Impact

Championing Gender Equality with Amb. Geeta Rao Gupta

Podcast Episode by Hadeil Ali — September 10, 2024

Audio Briefs Banner

Podcast Episode by Daniel F. Runde, Leah Kieff, and Thomas Bryja — September 10, 2024

Audio Briefs

Partnering with Middle Eastern Countries to Boost U.S. Minerals Security

Podcast Episode by Gracelin Baskaran — September 9, 2024

Past Events

Photo: Taylor Hill/Getty Images

Solving the World’s Hardest Problems with Mellody Hobson: Closing the Racial Wealth Gap

Photo: Scott Kennedy/CSIS

China’s Third Plenum: A Plan for Renewed Reform?

Photo: WANG ZHAO/AFP via Getty Images

Is It Me or the Economic System? Changing Chinese Attitudes Toward Inequality: A Big Data China Event

Photo:	Sigrid Gombert/Getty Images

Report Launch: The Role of Trust in Advancing Equity in Innovation

Photo: Raees Uzhunnan/Getty Images

U.S.-India Clean Energy Partnership for 450 GW

Photo: Drew Angerer/Getty Images

U.S.-ROK Bilateral Dialogue for Strengthening U.S.-ROK Alliance

Photo: Anna Moneymaker/Getty Images

Report Launch: Beyond Economics: How U.S. Policies Can Undermine National Security Goals

Photo: Andrew Harrer/Bloomberg via Getty Images

North American Economic Security in an Era of Geopolitical Uncertainty

Related programs.

research studies about economics

Navin Girishankar

William Alan Reinsch

William Alan Reinsch

Scott Kennedy

Scott Kennedy

Daniel F. Runde

Daniel F. Runde

Richard M. Rossow

Richard M. Rossow

5Baskaran

Gracelin Baskaran

Erin L. Murphy

Erin L. Murphy

Bhawna Prakash

Bhawna Prakash

All economics content, type open filter submenu.

  • Article (1383)
  • Event (558)
  • Expert/Staff (88)
  • Podcast Episode (346)
  • Report (361)

Article Type open filter submenu

Report type open filter submenu, region open filter submenu.

  • Afghanistan (22)
  • Africa (121)
  • Americas (461)
  • Arctic (17)
  • Asia (1032)
  • Australia, New Zealand, and Pacific (65)
  • Caribbean Security (57)
  • Central Asia (42)
  • China (639)
  • Eastern Europe (34)
  • Egypt and the Levant (4)
  • Europe (236)
  • European Union (118)
  • India (186)
  • Japan (173)
  • Korea (134)
  • Middle East (85)
  • North Africa (17)
  • North Africa (6)
  • North America (347)
  • Pakistan (26)
  • Russia (79)
  • Russia and Eurasia (122)
  • South America (120)
  • Southeast Asia (179)
  • Sub-Saharan Africa (44)
  • The Gulf (9)
  • The South Caucasus (18)
  • Turkey (30)

"On Day One": A U.S. Economic Contingency Plan for a Taiwan Crisis 

Please join the Freeman Chair in China Studies for a discussion with Eyck Freyman and Hugo Bromley on their recent report "On Day One: An Economic Contingency Plan for a Taiwan Crisis" (Hoover Institution Press, July 2024).

Event — September 19, 2024

Photo: nakimori/Adobe Stock

Navigating the National Security Inflection Point: A Conversation with the Assistant Secretary for Export Enforcement

Please join the CSIS Economic Security and Technology Department for an armchair discussion between the Assistant Secretary for Export Enforcement and Scholl Chair in International Business on the United States’ export enforcement and compliance policies.

Event — September 12, 2024

Photo: Annabelle Chih/Getty Images

Enhancing U.S.-ROK Economic Security Cooperation

Please join the Korea Chair at the Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS) for enhancing U.S.-ROK economic security cooperation. 

Event — September 11, 2024

Photo: SeongJoon Cho/Bloomberg via Getty Images

The Trustee Chair hosts the launch of a report on the findings of a survey of over 600 Taiwanese businesses. The report finds that Taiwanese companies moving their value chains but are also pursuing various forms of diversification. Experts will discuss the implications for the international business community, Taiwanese politics, and U.S.-Taiwan relations. 

Photo: Scott Kennedy/CSIS

An audio version of “Moldova’s Gas Futures,” a new Critical Questions by CSIS’s Daniel F. Runde, Leah Kieff, and Thomas Bryja. This audio was generated with text-to-speech by Eleven Labs. 

Audio Briefs

Navin Girishankar: Economic Security and Technology at CSIS

Navin Girishankar, president of CSIS’s new Economic Security and Technology Department, joins the podcast to discuss his experience working at the Department of Commerce, Bridgewater Associates, and the World Bank, as well as CSIS’s renewed focus on economic statecraft and technology to address 21st-century security threats.

Podcast Episode by H. Andrew Schwartz and Navin Girishankar — September 9, 2024

CSIS the truth of the matter

This week, the Scholl Chair explores the origins and consequences of Chinese industrial overcapacity—and how countries impacted by dumping are starting to fight back.

Photo: Costfoto/NurPhoto/Getty Images

The CSIS Trustee Chair’s second formal survey of over 600 Taiwanese companies reveals they remain worried about the international environment and conditions in China, but are engaged in diversifying rather than fully decoupling their business from China.

Photo: Scott Kennedy/CSIS

An audio version of “Are the Chickens Coming Home to Roost?,” a new commentary by CSIS’s William Alan Reinsch. This audio was generated with text-to-speech by Eleven Labs. 

Podcast Episode by William Alan Reinsch — September 9, 2024

“Diversifying, Not Decoupling: Taiwanese Industry Responds to Geostrategic Risks”: Audio Brief with Scott Kennedy

A short, spoken-word summary from CSIS’s Scott Kennedy on his report with Andrea Leonard Palazzi, Diversifying, Not Decoupling: Taiwanese Industry Responds to Geostrategic Risks.

Podcast Episode by Scott Kennedy — September 9, 2024

research studies about economics

Search form

Make a Gift

Department of Economics

Undergraduate.

research studies about economics

UVA ECONOMIST RECEIVES PRESTIGIOUS ROSS PRIZE: From left to right: Vish Viswanathan (Duke University), John Geanakoplos (Yale University), Ana Fostel, and Adriano Rampini (Duke University)

research studies about economics

Veconlab Table at the Economic Science Association Meeting in Charlotte, NC

research studies about economics

CAN VOICE TRAINING SOLVE CLIMATE CHALLENGES? UVA RESEARCHERS ARE WILLING TO TRY

research studies about economics

Kenneth G. Elzinga and Charles A. Holt receives the Southern Economic Association' Distinguished Fellow Award

research studies about economics

AEA Distinguished Economic Education Award presented to Charles Holt

research studies about economics

Professor Leeper's recent Senate testimony

research studies about economics

New Faculty 2024

research studies about economics

She Was Going To Be a Lawyer. Then Ken Elzinga Intervened

research studies about economics

Academic research award: problem solvers for the planet

research studies about economics

The Economist Breaking Ranks to Warn of AI’s Transformative Power

research studies about economics

By Putting His Own Twist on the News, This UVA Alumnus Is Fulfilling a Dream

research studies about economics

What can Economics do for you? Learn about the Major and Minor

research studies about economics

Learn about the PhD program, admissions, and program structure

Discover More

research studies about economics

Faculty, Staff, and Graduate Student Contact and Background Information

IO/Theory Economics Workshop: Karam Kang

Global developement seminar, econometrics workshop: tba, macro workshop: benjamin lester.

More Events      Workshop Schedule

research studies about economics

Department News | 11/27/2023

Argentina is a textbook case of ‘fiscal dominance’.

research studies about economics

Career News | 03/31/2024

The 2024 economics undergraduate career forum.

research studies about economics

Graduate News | 05/02/2024

Economics grads students and faculty.

research studies about economics

Undergraduate News | 04/15/2021

Student council president abel liu named as uva’s latest truman scholar.

research studies about economics

Recent Faculty Publications

Elite schools and opting in: effects of college selectivity on career and family outcomes, amalia miller, suqin ge, elliott isaac,, effects of covid‐19 shutdowns on domestic violence in us cities, amalia r. miller, carmit segal , melissa k. spence.

research studies about economics

Learning the Optimal Recommendation from Explorative Users

Denis nekipelov fan yao, chuanhao li , hongning wang , haifeng xu.

research studies about economics

Learning from a Learning User for Optimal Recommendations

Denis nekipelov, fan yao, chuanhao li, hongning wang, haifeng xu.

research studies about economics

Balancing data privacy and usability in the federal statistical system

Denis nekipelov, v. joseph hotz , christopher r. bollinger, tatiana komarova , charles f. manski robert a. moffitt , aaron sojourner and bruce d. spencer.

research studies about economics

Access to Colleges, Human Capital, and Empowerment of Women

Sheetal sekhri, md.amzad hossain, pooja khosla, agricultural trade and depletion of groundwater, sheetal sekhri, access to toilets and violence against women, sheetal sekhri, kanika mahajan, amzad hossain.

research studies about economics

Water in Scarcity, Women in Peril

Sheetal sekhri, md.amzad hossain.

research studies about economics

The Impact of Covid-19 Containment Lock Downson MSMEs in India and Resilience of Exporting Firms

Sheetal sekhri, yutong chen, sisir debnathl vishal sekhri.

research studies about economics

Macroprudential Regulation Versus Mopping Up After the Crash

Anton korinek, olivier jeanne.

research studies about economics

Integrating Ethical Values and Economic Value to Steer Progress in Artificial Intelligence [

Anton korinek.

research studies about economics

Capital Controls: Theory and Evidence

Anton korinek, bilge erten, josé antonio ocampo,, returns to scale, firm entry, and the business cycle, vladimir smirnyagin.

research studies about economics

Beyond Health: Nonhealth Risk and the Value of Disability Insurance

Lee lockwood, manasi deshpande.

research studies about economics

Blame it on the rain: Rainfall variability, consumption smoothing, and subjective well-being in rural Ethiopia

Jonathan colmer, yonas alem,.

research studies about economics

Price Dispersion and Legacy Discounts in the National Television Advertising Market

Julie holland mortimer, sylivia hristakeva.

research studies about economics

International Portfolio Choice with Frictions: Evidence from Mutual Funds

Eric van wincoop; philippe bacchetta, simon tieche.

research studies about economics

The March of the Techies: Job Polarization Within and Between Firms

James harrigan, ariell reshef, farid toubal.

research studies about economics

Infrequent Random Portfolio Decisions in an Open Economy Model

Eric van wincoop; philippe bacchetta; eric young, can sticky portfolios explain international capital flows and asset prices, eric van wincoop; philippe bacchetta, margaret davneport, puzzling exchange rate dynamics and delayed portfolio adjustment, eric van wincoop; philippe bacchetta, the global capital flows cycle: impact on gross and net capital flows, eric van wincoop; scott davis ; giorgio valente, obvious manipulations, peter troyan, thayer morrill, essentially stable matchings, peter troyan, andrew kloosterman, david delacrétaz.

research studies about economics

Matching with Asymmetric Information: Priority Design and the Curse of Acceptance

Peter troyan, andrew kloosterman.

research studies about economics

Desirable Rankings: A New Method for Ranking Outcomes of a Competitive Process

research studies about economics

Rankings-Dependent Preferences: A Real Goods Matching Experiment

research studies about economics

A Theory of Simplicity in Games and Mechanism Design

Peter troyan; marek pycia.

research studies about economics

Policing in Patriarchy: An Experimental Evaluation of Reforms to Improve Police Responsiveness to Women in India

Sandip sukhtankar;gabrielle kruks-wisner and akshay mangla.

research studies about economics

Lapses in Long-Term Care Insurance

Leora friedberg, wenliang hou, wei sun, anthony webb.

research studies about economics

Capitalism and Democracy

Kenneth elzinga.

research studies about economics

Elbert Gary & Bill Gates: A Study in Antitrust Contrasts

Kenneth elzinga' l. jackson howell, jr., evangelical economics.

research studies about economics

In-Person versus Online Instruction: Evidence from Principles of Economics

Kenneth elzinga; daniel harper.

research studies about economics

In the Beginning: The Creation of the Economic Expert in Antitrust,”

research studies about economics

“Has Anheuser-Busch Let the Steam Out of Craft Beer? The Economics of Acquiring Craft Brewers

Kenneth elzinga; alexander mcglothlin.

research studies about economics

A framework for a sustainable craft beer supply chain

Kenneth elzinga; harish c. bahl, jatinder n.d. gupta.

research studies about economics

Christianity and Antitrust: A Nexus

Kenneth elzingal daniel a. crane.

research studies about economics

Infringing Use as a Path to Legal Consumption: Evidence from a Field Experiment

Julie holland mortimer ; hong luo.

research studies about economics

Efficiency and Foreclosure Effects of Vertical Rebates: Empirical Evidence

Julie holland mortimer ; christopher conlon.

research studies about economics

Empirical Properties of Diversion Ratios

Julie holland mortimer ;christopher conlon.

research studies about economics

General Equilibrium Effects of (Improving) Public Employment Programs: Experimental Evidence From India

Sandip sukhtankar;paul niehaus;karthik muralidharan.

research studies about economics

Ad Clutter, Time Use, and Media Diversity

Simon p. anderson martin peitz.

research studies about economics

Price Discrimination in the Information Age: Prices, Poaching, and Privacy with Personalized Targeted Discounts

Simon anderson, alicia baik, nathan larson.

research studies about economics

Reexamining the evidence on gun ownership and homicide using proxy measures of ownership

John pepper with karim chalak, daniel kim and megan miller, inflation's role in optimal monetary-fiscal policy, eric m. leeper and xuan zhou, optimal time-consistent monetary, fiscal and debt maturity policy, eric m. leeper and campbell leith and ding liu.

research studies about economics

Beyond Health: Non-Health Risk and the Value of Disability Insurance

Lee m. lockwood and manasi deshpande, sheetal sekhri, amzad hossain, and pooja khosla.

research studies about economics

Road capacity, domestic trade and regional outcomes

Kerem cosar, banu demir, devaki ghose, nathaniel young.

research studies about economics

Eric Young with Philippe Bacchetta and Eric Van Wincoop

research studies about economics

Multivariate Rational Inattention

Eric young with jianjun miao and jieran wu, pockets of predictability, leland farmer with lawrence schmidt and allan timmermann.

research studies about economics

Coordinated Capacity Reductions and Public Communication in the Airline Industry

Gaurab aryal, federico ciliberto (with benjamin leyden).

research studies about economics

Who Benefits from Credit Report Bans?

Leora friedberg (joint with richard hynes & nathaniel pattison).

research studies about economics

Rainfall Variability, Child Labor, and Human Capital Accumulation in Rural Ethiopia

Jonathan colmer, why are pollution damages lower in developed countries insights from high-income, high-particulate matter hong kong.

research studies about economics

Temperature, Labor Reallocation, and Industrial Production: Evidence from India

research studies about economics

Market Structure and Competition in Airline Markets

Federico ciliberto.

research studies about economics

Improving Last-Mile Service Delivery Using Phone-Based Monitoring

Sandip sukhtankar, karthik muralidharan, paul niehaus, jeffrey weaver.

research studies about economics

The Globalization of Postsecondary Education: The Role of International Students in the US Higher Education System

Sarah turner, john bound, breno braga and gaurav khanna, superstar exporters: an empirical investigation of strategic interactions in danish export markets, federico ciliberto with ina c. jakel.

Forms and Helpful Links

Nonrepresentativeness in Population Health Research: Evidence from a COVID-19 Antibody Study

Dutz, Deniz, Michael Greenstone, Ali Hortaçsu, Santiago Lacouture, Magne Mogstad, Azeem M. Shaikh, Alexander Torgovitsky, and Winnie van Dijk. "Nonrepresentativeness in Population Health Research: Evidence from a COVID-19 Antibody Study."  American Economic Review: Insights  6, no. 3 (2024): 313-323.

Insights

We analyze representativeness in a COVID-19 serological study with randomized participation incentives. We find large participation gaps by race and income when incentives are lower. High incentives increase participation rates for all groups but increase them more among under-represented groups. High incentives restore representativeness on race and income and also on health variables likely to be correlated with seropositivity, such as the uninsured rate, hospitalization rates, and an aggregate COVID-19 risk index.

Total Economic Impact Study Reveals a Return on Investment of 184% for Veracode Application Risk Management Platform Customers

research studies about economics

Research Finds Veracode Platform Improved Developer Productivity By 80% and Boosts AppSec Efficiency By 85%

Productivity Gains From Software Security Lead to a 20% Increase in Revenue

Burlington, Mass. – September 10, 2024 – Veracode , a global leader in application risk management, today released a commissioned study conducted by Forrester Consulting on The Total Economic Impact™ (TEI) of Veracode’s Application Risk Management Platform. The study revealed that Veracode delivered a 184 percent return on investment (ROI) to customers over a three-year period, as well as a material Net Present Value and a payback period of less than six months.  

Specifically, there were four key drivers of the economic impact: 

  • A 75 percent reduction in risk of software-based attacks    
  • 80 percent developer productivity recapture that can be reallocated to product innovation 
  • 85 percent efficiency gained in application security from increased automation 
  • Most noteworthy, a 20 percent growth in revenues from software security that drove new products, new market entries, speed to market, and security as a differentiator  

With software supply chain attacks on the rise, security and DevSecOps leaders need ways to source solutions that demonstrably protect their organizations, while helping them prove the value of application risk management. Forrester conducted the TEI study to examine the potential ROI for enterprises using the Veracode platform. Based on a series of interviews with Veracode customers, Forrester constructed a $2 billion “composite organization,” with 10,000 employees, 800 developers, and a business goal of increasing development velocity in support of revenue growth. The findings below are representative of these aggregated insights. 

Reduced Risk of Software-based Attacks  

Use of the Veracode platform resulted in a 75 percent decrease in the risk of a software supply chain-based attack which reduced associated breach costs for the study’s composite customer by $1.5 million over three years. The composite analysis also revealed annual financial benefits of about $7.1 million per year over a three-year engagement versus an upfront cost of $2.5 million, inclusive of platform fees, internal and third-party development costs, ongoing administration adoption, training and development. When added together, the average NPV, or the total value of an investment opportunity for Veracode customers over three years, stood at $4.6 million, with a payback period of less than six months. 

As one study participant, an Application Security Engineer, noted, “We have managed to eliminate all high and very high vulnerabilities across all of the apps now for two months. We run the reports and scans every day, and for two months we have not seen a single high- or very high-severity vulnerability show up. So, they’re not just fixing them; they’re preventing them by the reuse of known secure functions and modules across the code base.” 

Developer Productivity Unlocked  

The Forrester TEI analysis revealed that giving developers better visibility into security flaws earlier in the development process helps them rapidly reduce security debt. Use of Veracode’s platform resulted in an 80 percent improvement in developer productivity, totaling 70,000 developer hours and $3.41 million that could be reallocated to product innovation for the composite customer. 

“We started scanning about a year ago and have worked through [approximately] 60 percent of the outstanding open-source [software flaws]. That’s 20 years of tech debt we’ve worked through in that time, largely because we were able to have the controls in place for software releases with Veracode,” another study participant, a CISO in the healthcare technology field, stated. 

Efficiency Through Automation  

Forrester determined that customers experience an 85 percent reduction in the effort and time required to remediate flaws when using Veracode’s tooling to automate manual workflows. The study found the use of automation transformed the process and efficacy of AppSec programs by freeing up almost 25,000 hours—equivalent to nearly three years. The resulting productivity gains saved $1.3 million for the composite customer, as well as enabling Veracode customers to scale their scanning capacity. 

As one Head of Global Engineering Tools in the professional services sector commented, “I would say [prior to Veracode] we weren’t able to [triage] efficiently enough. … To do that properly then, you would spend at least 10 hours to evaluate [which scans to triage], and now you can do it by a glance.” 

Customers Gain Competitive Advantage  

Modern enterprises face the constant challenge of innovating and delivering secure code faster to stay ahead of the competition. The Forrester TEI study found using Veracode to accelerate and shift security earlier in the software development lifecycle enabled the composite customer to bring features and products to market faster, open new markets and revenue streams, and use security as a differentiator. Moreover, organizations increased their revenue by 20 percent, which made an additional $940,000 in profits for the composite customer directly attributable to using Veracode’s solution. 

Another study participant, a Director of Risk and Security, affirmed Veracode’s innovation and speed of delivery; “We’re constantly delivering new feature functions every two weeks. Back in the day, a customer might be sitting on a version for three years with no feature function improvement and then go through an upgrade that takes six or eight months to get it, whereas now we’re deploying new features and functions every two weeks.” 

Additional key findings of the Forrester TEI study included:  

  • Augmented reporting capabilities  
  • Higher levels of IT spend dedicated to security  
  • Optimized technology costs  
  • An improved security culture   
  • Improved developer experience and security maturity  

“Ensuring organizations are effectively securing their software against cyberattacks, while facing the reality of constrained budgets, has never been more critical.” said Tim Jarrett, Group Vice President of Product Management at Veracode. “The Forrester TEI study reaffirms that Veracode not only provides businesses with top-tier services, but also delivers meaningful returns and business impact to increase agility and innovation. I’m grateful to our customers for sharing their experiences and helping us demonstrate the true value of Veracode’s platform. This is why organizations place their trust in us every day.” 

The Forrester TEI study provides a framework to evaluate the potential financial impact of the Veracode platform on organizations. Forrester interviewed four representatives with experience using the Veracode platform. For the purposes of this study, Forrester aggregated the interviewees’ experiences and combined the results into a single, “composite organization” with $2 billion in annual revenue, 10,000 full-time employees, 1,000 managed apps, 800 developers, and a business goal of increasing development velocity in support of strategic revenue growth. 

For more information on the Total Economic Impact™ of Veracode, download the complete study and join a LinkedIn Live where the benefits will be discussed. 

About Veracode

Veracode is a global leader in Application Risk Management for the AI era. Powered by trillions of lines of code scans and a proprietary AI-assisted remediation engine, the Veracode platform is trusted by organizations worldwide to build and maintain secure software from code creation to cloud deployment. Thousands of the world’s leading development and security teams use Veracode every second of every day to get accurate, actionable visibility of exploitable risk, achieve real-time vulnerability remediation, and reduce their security debt at scale. Veracode is a multi-award-winning company offering capabilities to secure the entire software development life cycle, including Veracode Fix, Static Analysis, Dynamic Analysis, Software Composition Analysis, Container Security, Application Security Posture Management, and Penetration Testing.

Learn more at  www.veracode.com , on the  Veracode blog , and on  LinkedIn  and  Twitter.

Copyright © 2024 Veracode, Inc. All rights reserved. Veracode is a registered trademark of Veracode, Inc. in the United States and may be registered in certain other jurisdictions. All other product names, brands or logos belong to their respective holders. All other trademarks cited herein are property of their respective owners.

Press and Media Contacts

Veracode: Katy Gwilliam, Head of Global Communications, Veracode [email protected] +44.7584.341.110 Related Links veracode.com

BROWSE RESOURCES

Analyst Reports

Customer Stories

Tips and Tricks

Webinars, Videos, & Podcasts

Whitepapers and eBooks

IMAGES

  1. Economics-Research-Proposal-Topics-list.pdf

    research studies about economics

  2. PPT

    research studies about economics

  3. (PDF) Research Methods for Economics

    research studies about economics

  4. Economics

    research studies about economics

  5. 130 Excellent Economics Research Topics To Consider

    research studies about economics

  6. Encyclopedia of Economics Research (2 Volume Set)

    research studies about economics

VIDEO

  1. PhD Topics in Economics

  2. Surprise Rise In House Prices

  3. 10 Problems of Brexit: Why The Economic COSTS Keep Growing

  4. RES 2022: Economic Journal Lecture

  5. Interim Budget 2024 || Highlights & Analysis in Hindi || Complete Union Budget Important Point #kgs

  6. How Econometrics Revolutionised Economic Research

COMMENTS

  1. Economics: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Economics

    Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Economics

  2. The Review of Economic Studies

    The Review of Economic Studies | Oxford Academic

  3. National Bureau of Economic Research

    National Bureau of Economic Research | NBER

  4. RePEc: Research Papers in Economics

    RePEc: Research Papers in Economics

  5. Oxford Economic Papers

    Oxford Economic Papers

  6. Working Papers

    Working Papers | NBER

  7. Research in Economics

    Research in Economics | Journal

  8. Economic Studies

    Economic Studies scholars conduct rigorous research and policy analysis and communicate their findings to inform policymakers and the public in the areas of broad-based economic growth, economic ...

  9. Research

    The Reporter is a free quarterly publication featuring program updates, affiliates writing about their research, and news about the NBER. Subscribe to the Free Reporter. On July 1, the Program on Children was renamed the Program on Children and Families. This change, which better captures the range of research carried out by its 171 affiliates ...

  10. Highly Cited Articles

    Highly Cited Articles. The Review of Economic Studies is a premier journal in the field of economic research, with a reputation for publishing path-breaking papers in theoretical and applied economics.The quality and influence of research published in the journal is demonstrated by our latest Impact Factor, which shows that articles published in The Review remain highly read and cited by ...

  11. Economics

    Economics - Latest research and news

  12. Research

    Research | MIT Economics ... Research

  13. Studies in Economics and Econometrics

    Studies in Economics and Econometrics

  14. Studies in Microeconomics: Sage Journals

    Studies in Microeconomics

  15. The power of economics to explain and shape the world

    To add impact, Duflo says she and Banerjee tie lessons to current events and dive more deeply into a few economic studies. One class, for example, focused on the unequal burden the Covid-19 pandemic has placed on different demographic groups and referenced research by Harvard University professor Marcella Alsan, who won a MacArthur Fellowship ...

  16. Economic Growth: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Economic Growth

    Economic Growth. New research on economic growth from Harvard Business School faculty on issues including whether the US economy can recapture the powerful growth rates of the past, how technology adoption affects global economies, and why India's economy is expected to overtake China's. Page 1 of 19 Results.

  17. Methods Used in Economic Research: An Empirical Study of ...

    The methods used in economic research are analyzed on a sample of all 3,415 regular research papers published in 10 general interest journals every 5th year from 1997 to 2017. The papers are classified into three main groups by method: theory, experiments, and empirics. The theory and empirics groups are almost equally large. Most empiric papers use the classical method, which derives an ...

  18. Development Economics: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on

    New research on development economics from Harvard Business School faculty on issues including the between mental health and economic productivity, the "Argentina Paradox," and strategy and execution for emerging markets. ... This study presents a theory in which firms that borrow from an informal lender may see their growth stalled and remain ...

  19. About the NBER

    About the NBER

  20. Research Fields

    579 Jane Stanford Way. Stanford, CA 94305. Phone: 650-725-3266. [email protected]. Campus Map. "The Stanford Economics Department has two central missions: to train students at the undergraduate and graduate level in the methods and ideas of modern economics, and to conduct both basic and applied research in economics that pushes forward the ...

  21. Research

    Research | Department of Economics

  22. Economics & International Relations: News & Research

    Economics & International Relations: News & Research

  23. Department of Economics

    Department of Economics |. Academic research award: problem solvers for the planet. By Putting His Own Twist on the News, This UVA Alumnus Is Fulfilling a Dream. Veconlab Table at the Economic Science Association Meeting in Charlotte, NC. UVA ECONOMIST RECEIVES PRESTIGIOUS ROSS PRIZE: From left to right: Vish Viswanathan (Duke University), John ...

  24. The economic impacts of ecosystem disruptions: Costs from ...

    Recent research has documented increases in biodiversity losses (1, 2), which are suggested to have dire consequences on par with climate change (3-5). Economists and ecologists have repeatedly theorized that the reductions in the abundance and diversity of animals and plants ( 6 - 11 ) will result in large social costs ( 11 - 15 ), but ...

  25. Nonrepresentativeness in Population Health Research: Evidence from a

    "Nonrepresentativeness in Population Health Research: Evidence from a COVID-19 Antibody Study." American Economic Review: Insights 6, no. 3 (2024): 313-323. Abstract. We analyze representativeness in a COVID-19 serological study with randomized participation incentives. We find large participation gaps by race and income when incentives are lower.

  26. Household Food Security in the United States in 2023

    Economic Research Report No. (ERR-337) 52 pp September 2024 Household Food Security in the United States in 2023. by Matthew P. Rabbitt, Madeline Reed-Jones, Laura J. Hales, and Michael P. Burke. An estimated 86.5 percent of U.S. households were food secure throughout the entire year in 2023, with access at all times to enough food for an ...

  27. Total Economic Impact Study Reveals a Return on Investment of 184% for

    Research Finds Veracode Platform Improved Developer Productivity By 80% and Boosts AppSec Efficiency By 85%. Productivity Gains From Software Security Lead to a 20% Increase in Revenue. Burlington, Mass. - September 10, 2024 - Veracode, a global leader in application risk management, today released a commissioned study conducted by Forrester Consulting on The Total Economic Impact™ (TEI ...