• Skip to Main Content
  • Media Center

prb-hero

Resource Library

The Demographic Transition: A Contemporary Look at a Classic Model

March 1, 2005

demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

Population Bulletin vol 75. no.1 : An Introduction to Demography

Transitions in world population.

With the spread of the Industrial Revolution in the 18th century, dramatic changes began to occur in the populations of industrializing countries. But do the changes that occurred in Western Europe and the United States have relevance for modern countries just entering the industrial age? Students should be able to evaluate and apply models to explain changes in global demographic patterns, and use their assessments to predict future needs.

  • To understand the classic demographic transition (DT) model
  • To explain assumptions and limitations of the classic DT model
  • To construct graphs of contemporary demographic change
  • To explain contemporary demographic patterns in the context of the classic DT model

Content Standards AP Human Geography*: Unit II—Population Unit B. Population growth and decline over time and space 4. Regional variations of demographic transitions

Student Activities

Activity 1: Explaining Population Change

  • Activity 2: Global Population Patterns and Demographic Transitions
  • Activity 3: Can an Old Model Explain New Trends?

Lesson Resources

Transitions in World Population , p. 6 and pp. 7-11 ( PDF: 320KB )

Population: A Lively Introduction, 4th edition ( PDF: 260KB ) [Note: The page numbers provided refer to the pages of the publication, not the pdf file.]

Central Concepts: Demographic transition model; birth rate; death rate; natural increase

Throughout much of history human populations have been characterized by relative stability—high birth rates and high death rates fluctuating around a low growth equilibrium. Dramatic changes followed first the Agricultural Revolution some 8,000 years ago, and later the Industrial Revolution 250 years ago, when improvements in food supply and changes in health and hygiene triggered unprecedented population growth. In the 1930s and 1940s, demographers proposed a model to explain the demographic changes observed in Western Europe between the late 18th and early 20th centuries. This model—the Demographic Transition Model—suggests a shift from high fertility/high mortality to low fertility/low mortality, with an intermediate period of rapid growth during which declining fertility rates lag behind declining mortality rates. This classic model is based on the experience of Western Europe, in particular England and Wales.

Materials Needed

  • Reading:  Population Handbook, 5th edition  ( PDF: 463KB )
  • PowerPoint or overhead transparency of  The Classic Stages of Demographic Transition  ( PPT: 53KB )
  • Handout 1. “Data for Graphing” (provided below or  Excel: 22KB )
  • Graphing paper or graphing software (MS Excel)
  • PowerPoint or overhead transparency of “Demographic Transition in Sweden and Mexico” or the data (found in Handout 1) for making this graph ( PPT: 65KB )

Instructions

What is “Demographic Transition”?

Before beginning this activity, assign the readings as homework.

  • Explain the classic stages of demographic transition using the PowerPoint slide or overhead transparency listed above.
  • Have students construct a graph of birth and death rates in England using either graph paper or graphing software (MS Excel).
  • Compare the graph of England’s transition to the classic model.
  • What similarities and differences can be observed?
  • Discuss social and economic factors that account for the changes in population patterns over the past two centuries. [Encourage students to draw on their knowledge of world history to enrich this discussion.]
  • Show a graph of demographic transition in Sweden and Mexico using the PowerPoint or overhead transparency listed above. [See alternative strategy below]
  • Compare the transitions in these two countries to the classic model.
  • Why are the demographic experiences of these two countries so different?
  • Why did Mexico ‘s late start toward transition result in such dramatic growth?
  • Is Mexico typical of countries currently undergoing transition?
  • Does this mean that the classic model is no longer relevant?

Alternative Strategy: Instructions

Supply the following data and have the students construct the graph for analysis.

Activity 2: Global Population Patterns and Demographic Transitions

  • World Population Data Sheet  ( PDF: 304KB )

Refer to the current  World Population Data Sheet  by the Population Reference Bureau to answer the following questions.

How Do Demographic Characteristics Vary Among World Regions?

  • Calculate the percentage (to the nearest whole number) of the world’s population expected to be living in less developed countries in 2025 and in 2050.2025: _______________ 2050: _______________
  • Subtract the lowest rate from the highest rate for both crude births and deaths and enter in the chart.
  • Is the difference between more developed countries and less developed countries greater for the crude birth rate or the crude death rate? Why do you think this is?

Is There Correlation Between Demographic Indicators and Economic Well-Being?

Refer again to the current  World Population Data Sheet  to complete the chart below:

* GNI PPP refers to gross national income converted to “international” dollars using a purchasing power parity conversion factor. International dollars indicate the amount of goods and services one could buy in the United States with a given amount of money.

  • Use the data collected in the chart above to construct three simple scattergrams relating crude birth rate and GNI PPP/capita; crude death rate and GNI PPP/capita; and rate of natural increase and GNI PPP/capita. [Note: Graphs can be constructed either manually on graph paper or electronically using a software program such as MS Excel.]
  • In general, what is the relationship between each indicator and GNI PPP/capita? Phrase your response in the form of three generalizations. [for example, “the higher the CBR, the…the GNI PPP/capita”]
  • Identify countries that are outliers in each graph. How do you account for each country’s deviation from the general trend? [Note: This may require some research.]

Based on the data collected in the final chart above, speculate in which stage of the classic demographic transition model each of these countries would fall.

  • Which characteristics are most helpful in making decisions?
  • What additional information would be useful?
  • Refer to the  World Population Data Sheet  to gather more information to support an informed decision.
  • How does the model assist in categorizing countries? What are some limitations?

Activity 3: Can an Old Model Explain New Trends?

Introduction

The classic Demographic Transition Model is based on the experience of Western Europe, in particular England and Wales. Critics of the model argue that “demographic transition” is a European phenomenon and not necessarily relevant to the experience of other regions, especially those regions referred to as “less developed” or “developing.”

The underlying premise of the classic Demographic Transition Model is that all countries will eventually pass through all four stages of the transition, just as the countries of Europe did. Because the countries of Europe, as well as the United States, have achieved economic success and enjoy generally high standards of living, completion of the demographic transition has come to be associated with socioeconomic progress.

This raises several questions:

  • Can contemporary less developed countries hope to achieve either the demographic transition or the economic progress enjoyed by more developed countries that passed through the transition at a different time and under different circumstances?
  • Is the socioeconomic change experienced by industrialized countries a  prerequisite  or a  consequence  of demographic transition?

Part One: Does the Classic Demographic Transition Model Provide a Useful Framework for Evaluating Demographic Change in Contemporary Developing Countries?

  • Reading:  Transitions in World Population , p. 6 and pp. 7-11 ( PDF: 320KB )
  • Handout 1. “Data Tables” ( PDF: 11KB )
  • Graphing paper or graphing software such as MS Excel
  • Internet access for basic research

Assign the reading above before conducting this activity.

  • Review the classic Demographic Transition Model. Discuss some criticisms of its relevance to countries only now experiencing demographic change.
  • Ask students if the classic model has a place in contemporary population analysis, and explain that they will test the model in this activity.
  • Divide the class into four (or more—see note below) groups. Assign each group one of the countries for which data is provided in Handout 1.
  • Have students construct a graph showing the trends in birth and death rates and population growth.
  • Direct students to use an Internet search engine to locate additional information about population trends in the assigned country.

[Note: Data for additional countries can be found in the U.S. Census Bureau International Data Base ]

Part Two: Is the Demographic Transition Model Useful as a Framework for Evaluating Demographic Change?

  • PowerPoint or overhead transparency of “A Model” ( PPT: 39KB )
  • When students have completed their graphs and research, have each group report back to the class.
  • Now return to the original questions to discuss the classic Demographic Transition Model.
  • Is the Demographic Transition Model useful as a framework for evaluating demographic change in regions outside Europe and the United States?
  • Is it necessary that all countries share the experiences of Europe and the United States in order to pass through a demographic transition?
  • Is the socioeconomic change experienced by industrialized countries a prerequisite or a consequence of demographic transition?
  • Are there multiple ways to achieve a similar end?

This lesson plan is part of a teaching package, Making Population Real: New Lesson Plans and Classroom Activities .

* AP and the Advanced Placement Program are registered trademarks of the College Entrance Examination Board, which was not involved in the production of these lesson plans.

Demographic Studies

prb-hero

Glossary of Demographic Terms

Aerial view of crowd connected by lines

Data 101 Tutorials on the American Community Survey

Cover-Population-Handbook-v6-2011

Population Handbook

Oxford Martin School logo

Demographic transition: Why is rapid population growth a temporary phenomenon?

Death rates fall first, then fertility rates, and this leads to a slowdown of population growth..

Population growth is determined by births and deaths. Every country has seen very substantial changes in both: mortality and fertility rates have fallen across the world.

But declining mortality rates and declining fertility rates alone do not explain why populations grow. If these changes happened at the same time, the size of the population would not increase. What is crucial is the timing at which mortality and fertility changes.

The model that explains why countries go through a period of rapid population growth is called the ‘demographic transition’. It is shown in the schematic figure. It is a beautifully simple model that describes the observed pattern in countries around the world and is one of the great insights of demography. 1

As the graphic below shows, the demographic transition is a sequence of five stages:

  • Stage 1 – high mortality and high birth rates : In the past birth rates were high, but since the mortality rates were also high we observe no or only very small population growth. This describes the reality through most of our history. Societies around the world remained in stage 1 for many millennia as the long-run data on extremely slow population growth makes clear. At this stage the population pyramid is broad at the base as many children are born. But since the mortality rate is high across all ages – and in particular for children – the pyramid gets much narrower towards the top.
  • Stage 2 – mortality falls, but birth rates are still high: In the second phase the health of the population slowly starts to improve and the mortality rate starts to fall. Since the health of the population has already improved, but fertility still remains as high as before, this is the stage of the transition at which the size of the population starts to grow rapidly. Historically it is the exceptional time at which the extended family with many (surviving) children is common.
  • Stage 3 – mortality is low and birth rates begin to fall: At this stage the birth rate starts to fall and as a consequence the rate at which the population grows begins to decline as well. In our topic page on fertility rates we discuss in detail why fertility rates declined. But to summarize the main points: When the mortality of children is not as high as it once was, parents adapt to the healthier environment and choose to have fewer children; the economy is undergoing structural changes that makes children less economically valuable; and as women gain more power within society and within partnerships they tend on average to have fewer children than before.
  • Stage 4 – mortality and birth rates are low: Rapid population growth comes to an end in stage 4. At this stage the birth rate falls to a similar level as the already low mortality rate. The population pyramid is now box shaped; as the mortality rate at young ages is now very low the younger cohorts are now very similar in size and only at an old age the size of cohorts get smaller rapidly.
  • Stage 5 – the future of population growth will be determined by what is happening to fertility rates: The demographic transition describes changes over the course of socio-economic modernization. What happens at a very high level of development is not a question we can answer with certainty since only few societies have reached this stage. If fertility rates are rising again at very high levels of development — as the research by demographers Mikko Myrskylä, Hans-Peter Kohler, and Francesco Billari suggests — then population sizes might stabilize or even increase. However if the fertility rate stays below 2 children per woman then we will see a decline of the population size in the long run.

Timeline chart that shows 5 stages of the demographic transition. Birth and death rates are plotted on the y-axis. Death rates first fall, and are later followed by a decline in birth rates.

Empirical evidence for the demographic transition

Rapid population growth is a temporary phenomenon.

If fertility fell in lockstep with mortality we would not have seen an increase in the population at all. The demographic transition works through the asynchronous timing of the two fundamental demographic changes: The decline in the death rate is followed by the decline in birth rates.

This decline in the death rate followed by a decline in the birth rate is something we observe with great regularity and is largely independent of the culture or religion of the population.

The chart presents the empirical evidence for the demographic transition for five very different countries in Europe, Latin America, Africa, and Asia. In all countries, we observed the pattern described by the demographic transition, first a decline in mortality that starts the population boom and then a decline in fertility which brings the population boom to an end. The population boom is a temporary event.

In the past, the size of the population was stagnant because of high mortality. Now country after country are moving into a world in which the population is stagnant because of low fertility.

The chart shows the demographic transition (birth and death rates) in Germany, Sweden, Chile, Mauritius, and China.

England and Wales’s demographic transition

Perhaps the longest available view of the demographic transition comes from data for England and Wales.

In 1981, Anthony Wrigley and Roger Schofield published a major research project analyzing English parish registers—a unique source that allowed them to trace demographic changes for the three centuries prior to state records. 2

According to the researchers, “England is exceptionally fortunate in having several thousand parish registers that begin before 1600”; collectively, with their early start and breadth of coverage, these registers form an excellent resource. As far as we know, there is no comparable data for any other country over such a long period.

The chart shows the birth and death rates in England and Wales over the span of nearly 500 years. It stitches together Wrigley and Schofield’s data for the years from 1541 to 1861 with two other sources up to 2015.

As we can see, a growing gap opens up between the birth and death rate after 1750. During this period the population begins to increase rapidly in size. Around the 1870s, we begin to see the third stage of the demographic transition. As the birth rate starts to follow the death rate’s decline, that gap between the two starts to shrink, slowing down the rate of population growth.

Sweden’s demographic transition

In the next visualization we take a closer look at Sweden’s demographic transition. The country’s long history of population recordkeeping – starting in 1749 with their original statistical office, ‘the Tabellverket’ (Office of Tables) – makes it a particularly interesting case study of the mechanisms driving population change.

Statistics Sweden, the successor of the Tabellverket, has published data on both deaths and births since record keeping began more than 250 years ago. These records suggest that around the year 1800, the Swedish death rate started falling, mainly due to improvements in health and living standards, especially for children. 3

Yet while death rates were falling, birth rates remained at a constant pre-modern level until the 1860s. During this period and up until the first half of the 20th century, there was a sustained gap between the frequency of deaths and the frequency of births. It was because of this gap that the Swedish population increased.

Demographic transitions across the world

Today, different countries find themselves in different stages of the demographic transition. In the chart we see birth rates plotted against death rates: the two variables that determine the demographic transition.

Most high-income countries have reached stage four and have low birth and death rates.

For a history and literature review of the theory’s development, see: Kirk, Dudley. “ Demographic transition theory .” Population studies 50.3 (1996): 361-387.

Wrigley, E. A., Schofield, R. S., & Schofield, R. (1989). The population history of England 1541-1871. Cambridge University Press.

Before 1800 more than 20% of Swedish babies died before they reached their first birthday, and of those who survived, another 20% died before their 10th birthday (see Croix, Lindh, and Malmberg (2009), Demographic change and economic growth in Sweden: 1750–2050 . In Journal of Macroeconomics, 31, 1, 132–148).

Cite this work

Our articles and data visualizations rely on work from many different people and organizations. When citing this article, please also cite the underlying data sources. This article can be cited as:

BibTeX citation

Reuse this work freely

All visualizations, data, and code produced by Our World in Data are completely open access under the Creative Commons BY license . You have the permission to use, distribute, and reproduce these in any medium, provided the source and authors are credited.

The data produced by third parties and made available by Our World in Data is subject to the license terms from the original third-party authors. We will always indicate the original source of the data in our documentation, so you should always check the license of any such third-party data before use and redistribution.

All of our charts can be embedded in any site.

Our World in Data is free and accessible for everyone.

Help us do this work by making a donation.

Library homepage

  • school Campus Bookshelves
  • menu_book Bookshelves
  • perm_media Learning Objects
  • login Login
  • how_to_reg Request Instructor Account
  • hub Instructor Commons

Margin Size

  • Download Page (PDF)
  • Download Full Book (PDF)
  • Periodic Table
  • Physics Constants
  • Scientific Calculator
  • Reference & Cite
  • Tools expand_more
  • Readability

selected template will load here

This action is not available.

Social Sci LibreTexts

17.2E: Demographic Transition Theory

  • Last updated
  • Save as PDF
  • Page ID 8491

\( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \)

\( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)

\( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

\( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

\( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\)

\( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

\( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\)

\( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\)

\( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

\( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\)

\( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

\( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorA}[1]{\vec{#1}}      % arrow\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorAt}[1]{\vec{\text{#1}}}      % arrow\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorB}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorC}[1]{\textbf{#1}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorD}[1]{\overrightarrow{#1}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorDt}[1]{\overrightarrow{\text{#1}}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectE}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{\mathbf {#1}}}} \)

Learning Objectives

  • Break down the demographic transition model/theory into five recognizable stages based on how countries reach industrialization

Whether you believe that we are headed for environmental disaster and the end of human existence as we know it, or you think people will always adapt to changing circumstances, we can see clear patterns in population growth. Societies develop along a predictable continuum as they evolve from unindustrialized to postindustrial. Demographic transition theory (Caldwell and Caldwell 2006) suggests that future population growth will develop along a predictable four- or five-stage model.

In stage one, pre-industrial society, death rates and birth rates are high and roughly in balance. An example of this stage is the United States in the 1800s. All human populations are believed to have had this balance until the late 18th century, when this balance ended in Western Europe. In fact, growth rates were less than 0.05% at least since the Agricultural Revolution over 10,000 years ago.

Population growth is typically very slow in this stage, because the society is constrained by the available food supply; therefore, unless the society develops new technologies to increase food production (e.g. discovers new sources of food or achieves higher crop yields), any fluctuations in birth rates are soon matched by death rates.

In stage two, that of a developing country, the death rates drop rapidly due to improvements in food supply and sanitation, which increase life spans and reduce disease. Afghanistan is currently in this stage.

The improvements specific to food supply typically include selective breeding and crop rotation and farming techniques. Other improvements generally include access to technology, basic healthcare, and education. For example, numerous improvements in public health reduce mortality, especially childhood mortality. Prior to the mid-20th century, these improvements in public health were primarily in the areas of food handling, water supply, sewage, and personal hygiene. Another variable often cited is the increase in female literacy combined with public health education programs which emerged in the late 19th and early 20th centuries.

In Europe, the death rate decline started in the late 18th century in northwestern Europe and spread to the south and east over approximately the next 100 years. Without a corresponding fall in birth rates this produces an imbalance, and the countries in this stage experience a large increase in population.

In stage three, birth rates fall. Mexico’s population is at this stage. Birth rates decrease due to various fertility factors such as access to contraception, increases in wages, urbanization, a reduction in subsistence agriculture, an increase in the status and education of women, a reduction in the value of children’s work, an increase in parental investment in the education of children and other social changes. Population growth begins to level off. The birth rate decline in developed countries started in the late 19th century in northern Europe.

While improvements in contraception do play a role in birth rate decline, it should be noted that contraceptives were not generally available nor widely used in the 19th century and as a result likely did not play a significant role in the decline then.

It is important to note that birth rate decline is caused also by a transition in values; not just because of the availability of contraceptives.

During stage four there are both low birth rates and low death rates. Birth rates may drop to well below replacement level as has happened in countries like Germany, Italy, and Japan, leading to a shrinking population, a threat to many industries that rely on population growth. Sweden is considered to currently be in Stage 4. As the large group born during stage two ages, it creates an economic burden on the shrinking working population. Death rates may remain consistently low or increase slightly due to increases in lifestyle diseases due to low exercise levels and high obesity and an aging population in developed countries. By the late 20th century, birth rates and death rates in developed countries leveled off at lower rates.

Stage 5 (Debated)

Some scholars delineate a separate fifth stage of below-replacement fertility levels. Others hypothesize a different stage five involving an increase in fertility. The United Nations Population Fund (2008) categorizes nations as high-fertility, intermediate-fertility, or low-fertility. The United Nations (UN) anticipates the population growth will triple between 2011 and 2100 in high-fertility countries, which are currently concentrated in sub-Saharan Africa. For countries with intermediate fertility rates (the United States, India, and Mexico all fall into this category), growth is expected to be about 26 percent. And low-fertility countries like China, Australia, and most of Europe will actually see population declines of approximately 20 percent.

image

Conclusions

As with all models, this is an idealized picture of population change in these countries. The model is a generalization that applies to these countries as a group and may not accurately describe all individual cases. The extent to which it applies to less-developed societies today remains to be seen. Many countries such as China, Brazil and Thailand have passed through the Demographic Transition Model (DTM) very quickly due to fast social and economic change. Some countries, particularly African countries, appear to be stalled in the second stage due to stagnant development and the effect of AIDS.

  • Demographic transition theory suggests that populations grow along a predictable five-stage model.
  • In stage 1, pre-industrial society, death rates and birth rates are high and roughly in balance, and population growth is typically very slow and constrained by the available food supply.
  • In stage 2, that of a developing country, the death rates drop rapidly due to improvements in food supply and sanitation, which increase life spans and reduce disease.
  • In stage 3, birth rates fall due to access to contraception, increases in wages, urbanization, increase in the status and education of women, and increase in investment in education. Population growth begins to level off.
  • In stage 4, birth rates and death rates are both low. The large group born during stage two ages and creates an economic burden on the shrinking working population.
  • In stage 5 (only some theorists acknowledge this stage—others recognize only four), fertility rates transition to either below-replacement or above-replacement.
  • demographic transition theory : Describes four stages of population growth, following patterns that connect birth and death rates with stages of industrial development.

LICENSES AND ATTRIBUTIONS

CC LICENSED CONTENT, SHARED PREVIOUSLY

  • Curation and Revision. Provided by : Boundless.com. License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike

CC LICENSED CONTENT, SPECIFIC ATTRIBUTION

  • Introduction to Sociology/Demography. Provided by : Wikibooks. Located at : en.wikibooks.org/wiki/Introduction_to_Sociology/Demography%23Population_Growth_and_Overpopulation . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Boundless. Provided by : Boundless Learning. Located at : www.boundless.com//sociology/definition/replacement-level . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • carrying capacity. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/carrying_capacity . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • fertility rate. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/fertility_rate . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Slums. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Slums . License : Public Domain: No Known Copyright
  • Demography. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Demography%23Basic_equation . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Boundless. Provided by : Boundless Learning. Located at : www.boundless.com//sociology/definition/natural-increase . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • demography. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/demography . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Net migration. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Net%20migration . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • mortality rate. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/mortality_rate . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Us population. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Us_population . License : Public Domain: No Known Copyright
  • Introduction to Sociology/Demography. Provided by : Wikibooks. Located at : en.wikibooks.org/wiki/Introduction_to_Sociology/Demography%23Early_Projections_of_Overpopulation . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • World population. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/World_population%23Forecasts . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Projections of population growth. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Projections_of_population_growth . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Overpopulation. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Overpopulation%23Mitigation_measures . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Birth rates. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Birth%20rates . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • forecast. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/forecast . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Green Revolution. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Green%20Revolution . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Green Revolution. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Green_Revolution . License : Public Domain: No Known Copyright
  • Population Growth Forecasts. Located at : www.youtube.com/watch?v=b98JmQ0Cc3k . License : Public Domain: No Known Copyright . License Terms : Standard YouTube license
  • exponential growth. Provided by : Wiktionary. Located at : en.wiktionary.org/wiki/exponential_growth . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Demography and Population. March 15, 2015. Provided by : OpenStax CNX. Located at : http://cnx.org/contents/2cf134f9-f88e-4590-8c33-404ead13ab83@3 . License : CC BY: Attribution
  • Boundless. Provided by : Boundless Learning. Located at : www.boundless.com//sociology/...n-catastrophes . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Overpopulation. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Overpopulation . License : CC BY: Attribution
  • Introduction to Sociology/Demography. Provided by : Wikibooks. Located at : en.wikibooks.org/wiki/Introdu...hic_Transition . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • OpenStax, Demography and Population. February 19, 2015. Provided by : OpenStax CNX. Located at : https://cnx.org/contents/LPE0-fiO@2/Demography-and-Population . License : CC BY: Attribution
  • Demographic transition. Provided by : Wikipedia. Located at : en.Wikipedia.org/wiki/Demographic_transition#Summary_of_the_theory . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike
  • Population Growth Forecasts. Located at : http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=b98JmQ0Cc3k . License : Public Domain: No Known Copyright . License Terms : Standard YouTube license
  • Demographic-TransitionOWID.png. Provided by : Wikimedia. Located at : https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/F...sitionOWID.png . License : CC BY-SA: Attribution-ShareAlike

Demographic Transition Theories

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online: 01 January 2022
  • pp 1389–1393
  • Cite this reference work entry

demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  • Luoman Bao 3  

239 Accesses

Population transition theories ; Fertility transition theories

The theory of the demographic transition describes changes in population trends from high mortality and fertility to low mortality and fertility rates and provides explanations for the transition from economic, social, cultural, and historical perspectives. During the demographic transition, a population changes in size, age structure, and the momentum of growth. The demographic transition theory informs the process of population aging because it discusses two crucial demographic processes, fertility and mortality, that alter the proportion of young and older people in a population. The theory indicates that when a population has completed the demographic transition, the proportion of older people increases and the population grows older.

The demographic transition is “the eternal theme in demography” (Caldwell 1996 , p. 321). Scholars generally believe that, although with forerunners, the...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Angeles L (2010) Demographic transitions: analyzing the effects of mortality on fertility. J Popul Econ 23(1): 99–120. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-009-0255-6

Article   Google Scholar  

Bianchi SM (2014) A demographic perspective on family change. J Fam Theory Rev 6(1):35–44. https://doi.org/10.1111/jftr.12029

Blue L, Espenshade TJ (2011) Population momentum across the demographic transition. Popul Dev Rev 37(4):721–747. https://doi.org/10.1158/0008-5472.CAN-10-4002.BONE

Caldwell JC (1976) Toward a restatement of demographic transition theory. Popul Dev Rev 2(3/4):321–366. https://doi.org/10.2307/1971615

Caldwell JC (1996) Demography and social science. Popul Stud 50(3):305–333

Google Scholar  

Colby SL, Ortman JM (2015) Projections of the size and composition of the U.S. population: 2014 to 2060. Current population reports, P25-1143. Retrieved from https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2015/demo/p25-1143.pdf

Coleman D (2006) Immigration and ethnic change in low-fertility countries: a third demographic transition. Popul Dev Rev 32(3):401–446. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2006.00131.x

Dyson T (2001) A partial theory of world development: the neglected role of the demographic transition in the shaping of modern society. Int J Popul Geogr 7(2):67–90. https://doi.org/10.1002/ijpg.215

Dyson T (2011) The role of the demographic transition in the process of urbanization. Popul Dev Rev 37(Suppl):34–54. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2011.00377.x

Galor O (2012) The demographic transition: causes and consequences. Cliometrica 6(1):1–28. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-011-0062-7

Grieco EM, Trevelyan E, Larsen L, Acosta YD, Gambino C, de la Cruz P, … Walters N (2012) The size, place of birth, and geographic distribution of the foreign-born population in the United States: 1960 to 2010. Population Division working paper, 96. U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, DC. Retrieved from https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/working-papers/2012/demo/POP-twps0096.pdf

He W, Goodkind D, Kowal P (2016) An aging world: 2015, U.S. Census Bureau international population reports. U.S. Government Piblishing Office, Washington, DC

Kirk D (1996) Demographic transition theory. Popul Stud 50(3):361–387. https://doi.org/10.1080/0032472031000149536

Lam D (2011) How the world survived the population bomb: lessons from 50 years of extraordinary demographic history. Demography 48(4):1231–1262. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-011-0070-z

Lesthaeghe R (2010) The unfolding story of the second demographic transition. Popul Dev Rev 36(2): 211–251. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2010.00328.x

Lesthaeghe R (2014) The second demographic transition: a concise overview of its development. Proc Natl Acad Sci 111(51):18112–18115. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1420441111

Murtin F (2013) Long-term determinants of the demographic transition, 1870–2000. Rev Econ Stat 95(2):617–631. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00302

Rowland DT (2003) Demographic methods and concepts. Oxford University Press, New York

Thornton A, Binstock G, Yount KM, Abbasi-Shavazi MJ, Ghimire D, Xie Y (2012) International fertility change: new data and insights from the developmental idealism framework. Demography 49(2):677–698. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-012-0097-9

Weeks JR (2016) Population: an introduction to concepts and issues, 12th edn. Cengage Learning, Boston

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Sociology, California State University, Los Angeles, Los Angeles, CA, USA

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luoman Bao .

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

Population Division, Department of Economics and Social Affairs, United Nations, New York, NY, USA

Department of Population Health Sciences, Department of Sociology, Duke University, Durham, NC, USA

Matthew E. Dupre

Section Editor information

The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, Hong Kong, China

Yuying Tong

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Cite this entry.

Bao, L. (2021). Demographic Transition Theories. In: Gu, D., Dupre, M.E. (eds) Encyclopedia of Gerontology and Population Aging. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-22009-9_655

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-22009-9_655

Published : 24 May 2022

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-030-22008-2

Online ISBN : 978-3-030-22009-9

eBook Packages : Social Sciences Reference Module Humanities and Social Sciences Reference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

Share this entry

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research
  • History & Overview
  • Meet Our Team
  • Program FAQs
  • Social Studies
  • Language Arts
  • Distance Learning
  • Population Pyramids
  • World Population “dot” Video
  • Student Video Contest
  • Lower Elementary (K-2)
  • Upper Elementary (3-5)
  • Middle School (6-8)
  • High School (9-12)
  • Browse all Resources
  • Content Focus by Grade
  • Standards Matches by State
  • Infographics
  • Articles, Factsheets & Book Lists
  • Population Background Info
  • Upcoming Online Workshops
  • On-Demand Webinar Library
  • Online Graduate Course
  • Request an Online or In-person Workshop
  • About Teachers Workshops
  • About Online Teacher Workshops
  • Pre-Service Workshops for University Classes
  • In-Service Workshops for Teachers
  • Workshops for Nonformal Educators
  • Where We’ve Worked
  • About the Network
  • Trainer Spotlight
  • Trainers Network FAQ
  • Becoming a Trainer
  • Annual Leadership Institutes
  • Application

demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

Classroom Activities for Teaching About Population Growth: Webinar Recap

Free easy-to-use lesson plans for virtual, blended, or in-person classrooms.

By Lindsey Bailey | October 16, 2020

Why populations grow is one of the most foundational questions when considering environmental and social issues, and earlier this month, we held a webinar to support educators in teaching this important demographic concept. A fantastic group of 74 teachers joined us, and we had the opportunity to share lesson plans and tools that can be used in both face-to-face and virtual classrooms. In case you missed it, here’s a quick recap of what we covered (with links to all the shared materials!).

Three Lesson Plans (with Virtual Adaptations) for Teaching Why Populations Grow

In this post, we’ll summarize the easy-to-use lessons that we shared for teaching about why populations grow and will explain how to adapt the lessons for a virtual classroom. Digital adaptations are made using Google Sheets and Google Slides and we will provide links for you to copy, use, and share with your own students. We also recorded the webinar, and encourage you to check it out – watch the webinar now !

A Visual Demonstration of the Relationship Between Birth and Death Rates

The lesson Stork and the Grim Reaper is a powerful visual, showing how birth rates and death rates interact to influence the rate of population growth. The lesson is a demonstration using two bowls of water. One bowl should be transparent (a glass or plastic Tupperware container works well) and represents planet Earth; the water inside this bowl represents our global population (it can be helpful to use blue food coloring to make the water more visible). The second bowl should be opaque so students do not see, or focus on, the water in it.

To prepare the demonstration, you will need two student volunteers, one to represent the global birth rate and one to represent the global death rate. Give the student representing birth rate the “Stork” necklace and a 1 cup measure, and the student representing the death rate the “Grim Reaper” necklace a ⅓ cup measure. (Currently, the global death rate is approximately one-third of the global birth rate.)

Screenshot of Stork and the Grim Reaper webinar activity demonstration

To start the demonstration, have the Stork add one scooper (1 cup) of water to the bowl representing our planet, symbolizing people being born, or added, to our global population. Then, have the Grim Reaper remove a scooper (1/3 cup) from the same bowl, representing people dying. The Stork and the Grim Reaper continue in turn while students observe what happens to the blue water that represents population. Students will see that because the birth rate is so much higher than the death rate (the scooper is so much larger) the water continues to rise.

Since this lesson is a demonstration, it can be done easily through a live video share in a virtual setting. To extend the lesson, try finding the birth and death rate equivalents for different countries around the world and comparing countries based on their rate of growth (or lack of growth).

Analyzing the Impact of Age-Structure Using Population Pyramids

Population Pyramids are a foundational tool for investigating population age-structures and therefore, growth patterns. In Power of the Pyramids , students are tasked with creating population pyramids for an assigned country, using provided age-sex data. The lesson provides data for six different countries – China, India, Guatemala, U.S., Nigeria, and Germany – and we recommend having pairs of students graph different countries.

Once all the graphs are completed, have each group share out, and save lots of time for analysis and discussion! Students will notice that the graphs look very different: some triangular, some more rectangular, and one (Germany) an inverse triangle. Using critical thinking, students can discuss which countries are experiencing the fastest and slowest rates of population growth, based on their pyramid shape. HINT! Countries with more triangular shaped pyramids are growing the fastest since the majority of the population is either currently in, or almost in, their reproductive years, and younger cohorts are larger than those above them on the pyramid.

Screenshot of India population pyramid from Power of the Pyramid lesson plan google slides

To do this population pyramid lesson digitally , have students use our Google Sheet to complete their graphing. Each tab of the Sheet has data for a different country, and students use the “paint bucket” tool to fill in bars on a pre-made graph template. Once graphing is complete, students can flip between completed country graphs to see the diversity of shapes and discuss implications.

Investigating How Societal Factors Impact Fertility Rates

There are many social and economic factors that impact fertility rates around the world. The lesson Demographically Divided World explores these factors and asks students to consider the validity of the Demographic Transition Model (DTM) and how it applies to certain countries.

After reviewing the map overlays of fertility and life expectancy data found on the interactive site www.worldpopulationhistory.org , six students take on the role of regional representatives to share statistics on factors that impact fertility rates. Standing at the front of the classroom, each regional representative shares their region’s total fertility rate with the class. Next, representatives read statistics for four factors that impact fertility: percent of girls not in school, infant mortality rate, adolescent fertility rate, and percent of female contraceptive use. For each factor, the following sequence is repeated: regional representatives read their statistic to the class, the class discusses how and why the factor impacts fertility rates, students determine whether a higher number or lower is more ideal for lowering fertility rates, then regional representatives line up in order of least ideal to most ideal. Students take note of the orders of the regions, brainstorm other factors that influence fertility, and discuss variations in fertility within each region.

Screenshot of Demographically Divided World lesson plan google slide

For the remainder of the lesson, students analyze the Demographic Transition Model, first learning about the model by using a data visualization from Gapminder.org and then researching an assigned country to determine where it falls within the DTM.

The first, third, and fourth parts of the lesson are already easily done in a virtual format, since they are completed using web based tools or independent research. To complete Part 2 of the lesson (where students are regional representatives), share this Google Slide deck with your students, along with the Region Cards. The six regional representatives will read statistics from their cards, and the class can discuss the statistics just as they would in person. Rather than lining up in the classroom from most to least ideal in terms of lowering fertility, a volunteer will slide the region tiles on the Slides into the correct order for each factor. To review the concept of the DTM, try this interactive tool using a Google Slide where students slide DTM characteristics into columns for the appropriate DTM stage.

More Resources for Teaching About Population Growth

Here at PopEd we’ve been focusing on why populations grow for the past two months and have been sharing lots of helpful lesson plans, tools, and resources. To find everything we’ve shared so far, follow us on Facebook , Twitter , or Instagram and search the hashtag #PopEdWhyPopulationsGrow. Let us help make teaching this important topic easier, more fun, and engaging despite this new virtual world!

About Population Education

Population Education provides K-12 teachers with innovative, hands-on lesson plans and professional development to teach about human population growth and its effects on the environment and human well-being. PopEd is a program of Population Connection. Learn More About PopEd .

Privacy Overview

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings

Preview improvements coming to the PMC website in October 2024. Learn More or Try it out now .

  • Advanced Search
  • Journal List
  • HHS Author Manuscripts

Logo of nihpa

THE SECOND DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION THEORY: A Review and Appraisal

Batool zaidi.

PhD candidate, Sociology Department, The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill

S. Philip Morgan

Alan Feduccia Professor, Sociology Department and Director, Carolina Population Center, The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill

References to the second demographic transition (SDT) concept/theoretical framework have increased dramatically in the last two decades. The SDT predicts unilinear change toward very low fertility and a diversity of union and family types. The primary driver of these changes is a powerful, inevitable and irreversible shift in attitudes and norms in the direction of greater individual freedom and self-actualization. First, we describe the origin of this framework and its evolution over time. Second, we review the empirical fit of the framework to major changes in demographic and family behavior in the U.S., the West, and beyond. As has been the case for other unilinear, developmental theories of demographic/family change, the SDT failed to predict many contemporary patterns of change/difference. Finally, we review previous critiques and identify fundamental weaknesses of this perspective, and provide brief comparisons to selected alternative approaches.

I. INTRODUCTION

The demographic transition, i.e., the transition from high to low death and birth rates, absorbed demographers’ attention for much of the second half of the 20 th Century. This empirical and theoretical attention produced an impressive set of mechanisms that together provide a compelling explanation for the decline in vital rates (see Casterline 2003 ; Bongaarts and Watkins 1996 ). However, for understanding fertility changes within already low-fertility populations, the demographic transition literature offers little. Building on and against this classical tradition, the framework of a “second demographic transition” (SDT) has become a population researcher’s “go-to” concept/theoretical framework for studying family/fertility change in contemporary Europe as well as the Western world more broadly (see for example Bianchi 2014 ; Sobotka 2008 ; McLanahan 2004 ). It is now also being proposed for understanding family change in Asian and Latin American countries ( Esteve et al 2012 ; Esteve et al 2012b ; McDonald 2009 ; Atoh et al 2004 ).

The second demographic transition entails “sustained sub-replacement fertility, a multitude of living arrangements other than marriage, the disconnection between marriage and procreation, and no stationary population” ( Lesthaeghe and Surkyn 2008 , pp.82; Lesthaeghe 2010 , pp. 211; Lesthaeghe 2014 , pp 18112). The primary driver of these trends is the cultural shift toward postmodern attitudes and norms (i.e., those stressing individuality and self-actualization) ( van de Kaa 2001 ). At the macro level the SDT provides a view of how societies evolve over time, stressing the role of ideational change in bringing about a package of demographic/family behaviors. At the individual level, the SDT framework offers individuals’ value orientations as the principal determinants of persons’ fertility and family behavior.

Originally proposed in 1986 by two European demographers, Ron Lesthaeghe and Dirk van de Kaa, the SDT framework/theory/concept (used in multiple ways in the literature) gained considerable traction in the 1990s ( Billari and Liefbroer 2004 ). By the turn of the century it had become “the theory of the decade…that launched a thousand research projects” ( Coleman 2004 , pp. 11). Figure 1 (right axis) shows the increase in peer-reviewed articles in the social science journals that mention “second demographic transition” in their text. Google Scholar data (left axis), that includes books and reports, provide many more citations and shows a similar, dramatic, upward climb.

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is nihms833966f1.jpg

Citations to the Second Demographic Transition (SDT): Peer-reviewed publications and Google Scholar cites

This review’s next section focuses on the content and scope of the SDT, and how they have evolved over time. The subsequent section assesses the fit of empirical evidence with the SDT. The final section reviews criticisms aimed at the SDT and briefly discusses some alternative approaches. We conclude with an appraisal that raises concerns about this widely used perspective. Specifically, the SDT clings to a problematic developmental perspective and as an inevitable result is inconsistent with important features of family and fertility in developed country contexts.

II. THE SECOND DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION

A. original statements.

Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa coined the term ‘second transition’ in 1986 ; the phrase appeared in the title of the introductory chapter of a special volume (published in Dutch) on the demographic situation in low fertility countries ( Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa 1986 ). Initially, Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa offered the second transition as a possible phenomenon (SDT was followed by a question mark in the title of the chapter). A year later, the Population Reference Bureau commissioned van de Kaa to write a bulletin on the demographic situation in Europe and van de Kaa titled this piece Europe’s Second Demographic Transition ( van de Kaa 1987 ). This bulletin became the seminal and most cited work on SDT; according to Google (accessed on 7.21.16) it has been cited 2270 times.

Examining demographic change in 30 European countries, van de Kaa (1987 , pp.5) argued that “the principal demographic feature of this second transition is the decline in fertility from somewhat above the ‘replacement’ level of 2.1 births per woman…to a level well below replacement.” The driving force behind this transition was ideational change -- a dramatic shift from altruistic to individualistic norms and attitudes ( van de Kaa, 1987 , pp. 5; van de Kaa 2002 , pp.5)

According to van de Kaa (1987) , the second demographic transition began in Europe after World War II. He argued that the war led to an increase in premarital intercourse and the age at first sexual intercourse declined in the postwar period. However, social attitudes were slower to change and marriage was still required for legitimacy and acceptability of sexual relations. As a result the age at marriage declined during this period. The improvement in socio-economic conditions after the war made children more affordable and thus fertility rates also increased up until the 1960s (pp.10).

Van de Kaa (1987 , pp. 10–11) proposed that early marriages loosened the temporal link between marriage and childbearing, as young married couples waited to have children until they were financially ready. Advances in contraceptive technology, with the introduction of the pill and IUD, further weakened the link between the two. The rise in divorce and separation along with the decoupling of sexual relationships and procreation led to a decline in marriage rates and an increase in cohabitation. After initially persisting, the pressure to marry by the time of first birth gave way as well (i.e., nonmarital fertility rose). Marriage (and consensual unions) no longer primarily reflected the desire for children and fertility rates declined well below replacement levels.

This is the “standard” sequence of events during the SDT ( van de Kaa 1987 , pp.11). van de Kaa (1987) acknowledged that changes in family formation in all 30 countries would not evolve according to this ‘standard’ sequence, but they would all experience the four basic features of the transition to below replacement fertility, and could be grouped according to where they were in the sequence (see Table 1 , column 1). Three of these features were related to changes in family formation and structure, and one captures the shift in contraceptive use (from preventive to self-fulfilling). Van de Kaa (1987 , pp.9) argued that while the timing and speed of the sequence of this second transition could differ substantially, there was still evidence of “logical ordering”.

Key aspects/phases of the SDT and recent elaborations

Lesthaeghe’s (1995) chapter “The Second Demographic Transition in Western Countries: An Interpretation”, which is the second most cited work on the SDT, with 1188 citations (Google scholar as of 07.21.16), built on van de Kaa’s description by further codifying the features of SDT and their sequence into three phases (see Table 1 , column 2). In a more recent statement, Lesthaeghe (2010 , cited 547 times, Google Scholar 8/1/2016) elaborates the SDT in response to conflicting empirical evidence and a set of criticisms by his peers. We return to this evidence and criticism below, but Lesthaeghe (2010) acknowledged different rates of social and demographic change and some variation in developmental paths. He also allowed for some heterogeneity in the end stage. However, he does so without removing the SDT’s fundamental developmental character – a feature we critique in our concluding appraisal.

B. The (first) demographic transition

For some readers, a discussion of the second demographic transition (SDT) begs for a description of, and links to, the first. As noted at the outset, the (first) demographic transition (DT) refers to the decline of fertility and mortality from high levels to low levels, with an intervening period of rapid population growth caused by an earlier and more rapid decline in mortality (than fertility). According to early statements of the demographic transition theory, the driver of these changes was industrialization (and associated social and economic development, i.e., modernization) that both increased children’s likelihood of survival and increased their cost to parents. These changes, in turn, increased motivation for reduced family size but did not undermine the universal expectation of marriage and parenthood. This description of change was based on patterns in the West but the scope of the theory was assumed to be global. Demographers posited that this demographic transition was inevitable, unilinear and irreversible ( Casterline 2003 ).

The massive, two-decade long European Fertility Project (Coale and Watkins 1986) assessed the fit of European historical data to this theory. While not discrediting the distal influences of industrialization, on a decadal time scale the fertility decline took on a pattern best described as “social contagion”, a change driven by new ideas and new options as opposed to individual decision-makers changing assessment of the “costs” of children ( Cleland and Wilson 1987 ). In other words, the decline of fertility in Europe showed a pattern suggesting “contagion” or “diffusion” – the best predictor of fertility decline for European provinces was the fertility behavior of neighboring provinces – rather than structural changes.

Lesthaeghe contributed greatly to the European fertility project through his early empirical work, The Decline of Belgian fertility, 1800–1970 ( Lesthaeghe 1977 ), and his analyses of the European Project’s multi-nation provincial data ( Lesthaeghe and Wilson 1986 ). He argued that new modes of thinking were fundamental to the speed and timing of fertility decline. These new modes of thinking involved the social acceptability and multiple advantages of controlling fertility. Subsequent fertility declines among developing countries in the post WWII period were of similar character (see Cleland and Wilson 1987 ; Bongaarts and Watkins 1996 ). The role of new ideas legitimating small family size and family planning are now central to the DT.

Why is the second demographic transition (SDT) not just a continuation of the first? Given the findings of the European Fertility Project on the role of “new modes of thinking” one possible narrative would stress continuity in the mechanisms producing change. But instead the proponents of SDT argue that the focal phenomenon changed – it was no longer smaller family size; it became fertility postponement and increased voluntary childlessness ( Lesthaeghe 2010 , pp. 216; van de Kaa 2001 , pp.302; van de Kaa 2002 , pp.10). The watershed between the first and the second demographic transitions is the shift in norms, from altruistic to individualistic ( van de Kaa 2002 , pp.5; Lesthaeghe 1995 , pp.19*; Lesthaeghe 2014 , pp.18112). New motivations underlying family formation behavior distinguished the second transition from the first. Greater female emancipation and individual autonomy were more central to SDT than they were to the first transition ( Lesthaeghe 1995 pp.18).

C. Theoretical motivations

Van de Kaa and Lesthaeghe mention three arguments that convinced them that the SDT was truly different from the DT, a discontinuity anchored in an irreversible shift in motivation and sentiment. We discuss these in turn.

Shift from king-child to king-couple

Van de Kaa and Lesthaeghe were heavily influenced by Aries’ claim that motivational shifts lead to fertility decline in the West over the twentieth century ( Aries 1980 ). Aries argued that even if the phenomenon of fertility decline experienced by the western world during the 1960s was not new, as pointed out by historians, the motivations behind it were; the resumption of fertility decline in the post-war period reflected a different outlook on life. To explain, Aries pointed out that “society has always controlled nature and domesticated sexuality” ( 1980 pp. 646). As early as the 16 th century, Europeans practiced fertility control in the form of delayed marriages. Malthus (1888) captured this view by claiming that the “passion between the sexes” was too great for married couples to practice fertility control via abstinence (and Malthus viewed other means as immoral). People did not think to control the frequency of intercourse to influence pregnancy; “automatic unplanned behavior” and surrender to impulses/destiny was the norm. Consistent with this Malthusian claim, marriage timing was the only mechanism of fertility control available ( Aries 1980 , pp.646).

Change occurred when couples began to plan their families using foresight and organization. For Aries (1980 , pp.646), this “revolution in sensibility” was perhaps as important as the French or Industrial Revolutions. He argued that this “planned parenthood” occurred before the availability of modern contraceptive technology, it relied on behavioral and sex-proximal methods (especially withdrawal and abstinence), and was in part successful because of a culture of self-control or non-coital, premarital eroticism.

Aries (1980) claimed that this is when affection became centered on children and the family, and families became more inward looking, organizing themselves in terms of children and their futures (note that he does not explain why this change took place). This led to a child-oriented society and to greater investment in children; these changes encouraged small families. During this period, birth control and lower fertility were the consequence of wanting one’s children to be upwardly mobile.

In response to the persistence of the child’s status as “king” during the Baby Boom period of rising fertility, Aries argued that younger women began to revolt against the burdens of motherhood. This was aided by the revolution in contraceptive technology – ‘the era of the pill began’ – and triggered a shift from “trustful modernity” to rebellion by the late 1960s (1980, pp.648). The post-baby boom resumption of declining birth rates was categorically different from that of the 1930s. According to Aries, the vast majority of couples did not now limit family size in order to move up the social ladder, but instead to free themselves from family obligations (1980, pp.648). And the availability of advanced contraceptive technology alone could not explain its wide acceptability and uptake.

Aries rejected alternative explanations and believed that the refusal to have an undesired child (by resorting to abortion) was a critical new phenomenon. It reflected the end of the “child-king” days, the child was no longer essential in couples’ plans; instead a child was just one of the components that might allow adults to blossom as individuals (pp.649). The couple and their relationship was now “king” and might make room for a child.

The proponents of SDT coined this the transition from the “king-child with parents” to a “king-couple with child” ( van de Kaa 1987 , pp. 11; van de Kaa 2002 , pp.5;). The justification of the SDT as a distinct transition rests heavily on this historical interpretation. Since the SDT is not solely about changes in birth rates, its proponents incorporated other theories of social change in their explanatory framework. Lesthaeghe (1995) argued that the SDT reflects and builds on not just Aries’ motivational shift theory, but several other irreversible revolutions in the Western world: the sexual revolutions proposed by Shorter (1971) , Westoff’s (1977) contraceptive revolution, as well as Sauvy’s (1960) characterization of the first transition as altruistic (and the second as individualistic). The shift to “king couple” or the rising importance of the adult dyad led to an increase in the minimal standards of union/marriage quality ( Lesthaeghe 1995 ).

The Maslowian drift and rise of individualism

Inglehart’s claims of a shift from materialist to post-materialist values also played a critical role in the elaboration of the SDT ( van de Kaa 1987 ; Lesthaeghe 1995 ; Lesthaeghe 2010 ). This value shift embodies the “Maslowian drift” that both proponents place at the heart of the second demographic transition – a shift toward higher-order needs of self-actualization and individual autonomy to motivate behavior once more basic needs like survival and safety have been satisfied ( Lesthaeghe 1995 ). The demographic changes since 1960 cannot be divorced from Inglehart’s (1990) ‘silent revolution’ that is argued to have taken place in Western nations as a result of the post-war economic affluence and security ( Lesthaeghe 1995 ; 2011 ). In recent statement of the theory, Lesthaeghe (2010 , pp.216) linked the Maslowian drift with a set of other transitions, the contraceptive revolution, the sexual revolution and the gender revolution, all fitting within a framework of rejection of authority and overhaul of normative structures.

Pushback against economic explanations

This SDT ideational reorientation occurred during peak years of economic growth. Both SDT proponents ( van de Kaa 1987 , 1994 ; Lesthaeghe 1995 ; Lesthaeghe 2014 ) acknowledge that SDT does not negate economic explanations of family change, such as those offered by Becker (1973 , 1974 , 1991 ) and Easterlin (1973 , 1976) . They acknowledged that the shifts in the quality-quantity tradeoff with respect to children as a useful concept in explaining the first demographic transition. Moreover, they credit rising female labor force participation as having an important role in the SDT. However, the economic models for fertility change allow for the reversal of trends experienced in the post-War period, and this is where the economic theories are at odds with one of the central tenants for the SDT – the irreversibility of changes in family and fertility (weakening of traditional family systems and below replacement fertility) ( Lesthaeghe 1995 , Lesthaeghe (2010 , pp.). In the language of classical economics, tastes and preferences have irreversibly changed.

SDT treats ideational change primarily “as exogenous influences that add stability to trends over and beyond economic fluctuations” ( Lesthaeghe 2014 , pp. 18113). So Lesthaeghe (1995 , 2010) emphasizes, that although compatible, the economic models are incomplete without the cultural/ideational explanations that SDT theory offers. He uses the strong empirical link between cohabitation and secularization to highlight this point, arguing that this link cannot be accounted for by Becker’s structural economic theory or Easterlin’s theory of labor market conditions ( Lesthaeghe 1995 ). Secularization is a manifestation of individual autonomy. Economic theories are incomplete without the Maslowian shift to higher order needs.

In summary, for the SDT, ideational change, as seen through the increase in individual autonomy, secularization, female emancipation, and post-materialism, is the central explanation, without which all other explanations are incomplete.

D. Expanding the SDT substantive and geographic scope

Initially the SDT was proposed as an explanation for below-replacement fertility and union formation changes in Europe. Early on the theory’s scope expanded to include mortality and migration patterns, but fertility/family change remained the primary focus. Specifically, SDT’s proponents ( van de Kaa 1994 , 1999 ) incorporated mortality and migration in a discussion of the unexpected and dramatic improvements in life expectancy (at birth as well as at advanced ages), and the initiation of guest worker schemes in Western European countries. Both van de Kaa and Lesthaeghe have argued that the role of migration changed. In the first transition (DT) emigration acted as a safety valve in maintaining equilibrium; in the second transition (SDT) immigration played a key role in maintaining national-level demographic homeostasis. “Replacement migration” is to the second demographic transition what replacement fertility was to the first transition ( Lesthaeghe 2010 , 2014 ). These changes in migration patterns contributed to an important divide in Europe’s population development halfway through the 20 th century ( van de Kaa 2002 ).

On the other hand, changes in mortality during the second transition (SDT) were not uniquely different from those that took place during the first transition. That it is to say that life expectancy continued to improve throughout the two transitions. However, according to SDT proponents, similar to fertility, mortality changes in the second transition were, and continue to be, strongly influenced by ideational and normative changes. That is, individuals took on greater responsibility for their health and adopted preventive measures that reflect value systems stressing self-fulfillment and individual freedom ( van de Kaa 2002 pp.22, 2004 pp.6). These SDT insights into the causes of migration and mortality change have not had the impact of those focusing on family and fertility.

The geographic scope of SDT has also expanded. Lesthaeghe (1995) aggressively extended the geographic reach of the SDT theory to all OECD countries ( Lesthaeghe 1995 ). SDT went from explaining changes in Europe to changes in industrialized nations more broadly, which meant the addition of the US, Canada, and Australia, New Zealand and Japan. In his more recent work Lesthaeghe (2010) claims that the SDT may have explanatory value for understanding worldwide family and fertility changes, given that the countries under consideration are “wealthy enough to have undergone the Maslowian drift” (pp. 234). Several East Asian countries, which have industrialized and urbanized, qualify for being considered as a testing ground for the SDT. But Lesthaeghe (2010) cautions that even in countries that meet this criteria, additional features are required for the identification of the SDT: below replacement fertility is linked to postponement; rising age at marriage conditional on female autonomy and partner choice; rise in prevalence and acceptance of premarital cohabitation; a link between demographic change and value orientation (pp234). He accounts for the fact that not all four of these features were present in all European countries before they entered the SDT by stating that the demographic characteristics of the SDT do not have to occur simultaneously but instead are likely to be lagged (2010, pp.234).

We should note, that the more recent works of van de Kaa and Lesthaeghe have diverged somewhat. Works by van de Kaa do not typically refer to the SDT as a theory or even a theoretical framework. Only a few years after his original piece on the SDT ( van de Kaa 1987 ), van de Kaa (1994) broadened the historical description to include two other dimensions of the social system in addition to culture/ideational change – structure and technology. Later he proposed treating the ideational change framework of the SDT as an anchored narrative or social history, with sub-narratives where necessary to explain variations ( van de Kaa 1996 ). He does, however, still support the validity of the SDT as a new demographic regime or “revolution” ( van de Kaa 2010 , pp.5).

Lesthaeghe’s work on the other hand has often used the term “SDT theory” or theoretical framework ( Lesthaeghe and Surkyn 2008 ; Lesthaeghe 2010 , 2011 , 2014 ). He is also much more vested in the ideational change explanation, with much of his work focusing on the contribution of the ideational change theory to understanding post WWII demographic change ( Lesthaeghe 1998 ), and establishing the links between the spread of post-materialist values and that change ( Surkyn and Lesthaeghe 2004 ). Much of the following discussion in this review focuses on Lesthaeghe’s highly visible and expansive use of the SDT, as opposed to van de Kaa’s historical and more circumscribed descriptive work.

III. EMPIRICAL ADEQUACY OF THE SDT

Lesthaeghe (e.g., 2010) has elaborated the SDT in response to emerging and (according to the SDT) unexpected demographic realities. This is an expected step in “the wheel of science” (or paradigmatic science) that re-establishes an acceptable fit between data and theory. Below we describe the fit of SDT predictions with observed changes, and we note elaborations of SDT (if any) to this evidence.

A. Union and family formation

Changes in union formation are at the heart of the second demographic transition. The SDT-related value changes are predicted to cause: mean age at marriage to increase, first marriage rates to decline, divorce rates to rise, cohabitation to become increasingly common and accepted, and the proportion of non-marital births to increase.

Broadly speaking, recent change in union formation are consistent with SDT expectations (see Cherlin 2012 : 585–586) as well as with what Cherlin (2004) called the “deinstitutionalization of marriage”. Age at marriage has increased worldwide ( Ortega 2014 ); Asian countries like Japan, Korea and Taiwan are now some of the latest-marrying countries in the world ( Raymo et al 2015 ) and even African nations are experiencing a rapid increase in age at marriage (Shapiro and Gebreselassie 2014). Further, there is no Western country where the proportions never-marrying have not increased from their levels in the early 20 th century ( van de Kaa 2002 ; Cherlin 2014 ). The decline in rates of first marriage rates has been even more dramatic in East Asian countries with economic growth matching Western nations, although variations by socioeconomic class remain ( Raymo et al 2015 ). In China age at marriage increased dramatically in the 1970s, but, has experienced relatively little marriage change (albeit in the expected direction) since. Marriage remains nearly universal and within a narrow age range ( Raymo et al 2015 ).

But when one looks more closely at the data questions arise. First, although marriage rates did decline in most industrialized countries after the middle of the 20 th century, these trends show a modest reversal in the vanguard nations of the SDT (Sweden and Denmark) as early as the 1990s ( van de Kaa 1994 ). Second, the mean age at marriage in low and middle-income countries is currently reaching the level that wealthier countries had reached in the 1970s ( Cherlin 2014 ), with several countries in Africa experiencing age at marriage nearly as high as that in contemporary Europe. Perhaps postmodern values are diffusing to new settings spawning an earlier start of the SDT ( Lesthaeghe 2010 : 244–45), in a way analogous to what Thornton calls “developmental idealism” (2001). Or more likely, high/rising ages at marriage are a response to greater economic crises and uncertainty (Shapiro and Gebreselassie 2014) or women’s dissatisfaction with the conflicts of rapidly changing economic participation and persistent traditional gender roles ( Frejka et al 2010 ; Jones and Yeung 2014 ).

The proponents of SDT claim that the weakening of the institution of marriage is one of the main characteristics of the SDT. This is seen through trends in both divorce and remarriage – with the SDT predicting that divorce rates increase and remarriage rates decrease. Demographic data show that, despite cross-national differences, divorce rates increased for almost all industrialized countries during the 1980s and 1990s ( van de Kaa 2002 ). However, in the last two decades some of these countries have experienced greater marital stability. Data for OECD countries shows that although all countries have experienced an increase in divorce from 1975 levels, half of the OECD countries saw a decline in divorce rates from 1995 ( OECD 2015 ). The East Asian nations have recently experienced an increase in divorce rates ( Raymo et al 2015 ). However, similar to the US ( Cherlin 2010 ), divorce shows a strong negative educational gradient in East Asia ( Raymo et al 2015 ), once again suggesting that the variation may have more to do with structural factors, like poverty, than increases in individualism or self-actualization. Moreover, in East Asia as well as in countries like the U.S., marriage remains a valued institution, with most young adults expressing the desire to marry at some point in the future ( Thornton and Young-DeMarco 2001 ; Manning et al 2007 ; Smock and Greenland 2010 ; Raymo et al 2015 ).

Increases in cohabitation predicted by the SDT are also widely observed. Several studies have documented the increase in both acceptability and prevalence of cohabitation across most industrialized nations. There are however sharp differences in cohabitation rates across countries. Even in Europe, the prevalence of cohabitation ranges from more than 75 percent in France and Finland to less than 10 percent in Italy and Poland ( Heuveline and Timberlake 2004 ). Cohabitation in the U.S. has increased among all social classes, however, duration remains shorter than in most other Western societies, and large proportion of these unions end in marriage ( Cherlin 2010 ). Moreover, in many places where cohabitation is common it continues to function as a precursor for marriage, rather than a substitute. In the U.S. couple’s often “slide” into a cohabiting union, rather than consciously choosing it as an alternative for marriage or as a rejection of authority or traditional norms ( Raley 2001 ; Manning and Smock 2005 ). Heuveline and Timberlake’s analysis (2004) shows that even among SDT leaders like Sweden close to two-thirds of cohabitations end in marriage.

Further, despite high levels of economic and social development and some of the lowest fertility rates, Asian countries such as Japan and South Korea have only recently started experiencing an increase in cohabitation, and it functions primarily as a precursor to marriage rather than an alternative ( Raymo et al 2009 ; Raymo et al 2015 ). Recent studies show that Latin America is experiencing a cohabitation boom ( Esteve et al 2012 ), although earlier studies analyzing similar data found early and persistent marriage in the region ( Fussell and Palloni 2004 ).

A final expected change in union formation by the SDT is the separation of fertility and marriage. Here there is great variability across and within developed countries ( Hiekel and Castro-Martin 2014 ; Hayford et al 2014 ). Non-marital fertility in the U.S. increased dramatically over the last 50 years, however, it is strongly correlated with poverty and low-education, pointing towards structural explanations more than cultural explanations of ideational change motivating behavior ( Bailey et al 2013 ; Cherlin 2010 ; Gibson-Davis et al 2005 ). Scholars find similar patterns for Russia as well ( Perelli-Harris and Gerber 2011 ). Non-marital fertility remains very low in many parts of Southern Europe and is rare even in the Asian countries said to be experiencing the second demographic transition ( Ravaneral et al 1999 ; Jones 2007 ; Raymo et al 2015 ).

B. Sub-replacement fertility

The second main SDT prediction is that below replacement fertility (via marked degree of postponement and definitive childlessness) will become a permanent feature in countries where material needs have been satisfied and the Maslowian drift has occurred ( Lesthaeghe 2010 ). Several studies find an increase in both attitudes and experiences of childlessness, not just in the West but Latin America as well ( Rowland 2007 ; Rosero-Bixby et al 2009 ; Merz and Liefbroer 2012 ).

A large literature on the phenomenon of low and lowest-low fertility has also emerged (e.g., Goldstein et al 2009 ; Morgan and Taylor 2006 ; Sobotka 2004 ; Kohler et al 2002 ; Morgan 2003 ; Frejka and Calot 2001 ; Foster 2000 ). At the end of the 20 th century, fertility rates in the western world varied substantially; some countries had fertility near replacement levels (TFR=2.0) and some at much lower levels (TFR<1.5). In fact, there was evidence of a recovery in fertility rates for several countries, many of whom were cited as leaders of the SDT (e.g., Scandinavian countries, France). Whereas fertility rates for Eastern and Southern European countries, who had begun their second transition later, had fertility rates below 1.5 ( Sobotka 2008 ). Fertility rates for the Asian countries, that had experienced few of the family formation shifts characteristic of the SDT, also remained well below 2 births ( Atoh et al 2004 ).

In sum, economically developed countries have sorted themselves into two groups: one approximating replacement level fertility (TFRs 1.8–2.1) and another with TFR’s of 1.5 and below (see Rindfuss and Choe 2015 ). The SDT did not anticipate this diversity initially. The proponents argue that while the SDT was a good predictor of postponement, it did not predict the variations in fertility rates or the divergence in recuperation rates ( Lesthaeghe 2010 ). They later distinguish between SDT aspects related to self-actualization and emancipation to account for recuperation differentials ( Lesthaeghe 2010 , 2011 ).

C. Links with ideational change

While some studies find links between post-materialism and postponement of marriage and nontraditional family norms and attitudes more broadly (e.g., Bystrov 2014 ; Gubernskaya 2010 ), the SDT’s posited link between ideational change (postmodernist values) and fertility decline does not find consistent empirical support, even in the regional heart of the SDT – North Western Europe. Contrary to original SDT predictions, van de Kaa (2001) found Inglehart’s postmaterialist values to be positively correlated with total fertility rates for a sample of European countries. Lesthaeghe ( 2010 , 2011 , 2014 ) has also acknowledged that the SDT theory affects components of fertility in opposite directions – some fostering postponement and thus lowering fertility, others fostering recuperation. Another study by Lesthaeghe and Lopez (2013) found that cohabitation and non-conventional family formation more closely mirror the “history of secularization”, whereas fertility postponement is more closely linked to structural factors like female education and employment.

Surkyn and Lesthaeghe (2004) used large-scale, cross-sectional data from the 1999–2000 European Values Survey for two Iberian, three Western European, and two Scandinavian countries and interpreted their results as supporting the ideational change hypothesis of SDT. Specifically, they show that “non-conformist orientation” is strongly linked with household type in all three regions. Married couples who never cohabited and cohabiting couples with children were at two ends of the conformist-orientation spectrum. On the other hand, Van de Kaa’s (2001) analysis of the World Values Survey data from the 1990s found no correlation between the proportion of extramarital births and postmodern or postmaterialist values, leading him to speculate that this might be explained by preexisting differences in the acceptability of childbearing outside marriage across European societies.

D. Empirical fit: an appraisal

Lesthaeghe (2014) maintains that the 1980s version of the SDT was correct in predicting a shift in value orientations, the spread of different partnership formation patterns, and sub-replacement fertility. Yet, it is hard to find a consistent pattern across countries, beyond perhaps the spread of cohabitation. Several studies show that even within Europe there is growing evidence of divergence rather than convergence between countries ( Billari and Wilson 2001 ; Billari and Liefbroer 2010 ). Of special importance is the failure of SDT to predict or account for the variation in low fertility. In some countries fertility continues to fall, and it is recuperating in others. Further, some countries leading the fertility decline, such as Japan, are lagging behind in cohabitation and non-marital childbearing rates. While countries that were late to transition, like those in Southern Europe and some in East Asia, now have some of the lowest fertility rates but have seen slow increase in cohabitation, divorce and non-marital fertility ( Ravaneral 1999 ; Dominguez-Folgueras and Castro-Martin 2013 ). The vanguards of the SDT, countries like Sweden with high postmaterialist and secular values, have started to experience recuperation in fertility rates.

Second, the SDT does a poor job accounting for within country variation. The SDT views these differential as a “cultural lag” as opposed to persistent differences linked to persistent inequality or identity differences, a point we return to in the critique below (also see Cherlin 2016 ). Finally, and of critical importance, the SDT’s posited link between ideational change (postmodernist values) and fertility/family change does not find consistent empirical support.

IV. CRITIQUES

The SDT has been challenged. We review a set of criticisms aimed at SDT and offer some additional ones. We then focus on two important forces, gender change and globalization, largely ignored in SDT.

A. Criticisms of SDT

We note above that the SDT predictions comport with some major features of recent family and fertility change. This is expected since the SDT was constructed to account for these facts. Further, as expected subsequent SDT statements are elaborated to account for “new facts” not predicted. But a key criticism related to “theory fit” takes aim at the heart of SDT – the Aries/Inglehart claim of the watershed changes in ideology that undergird the SDT – a shift from “materialism/post-materialism” (or the related “child-king” to “king couple”). This undergirding mechanism is problematic ( Coleman 2004 , pp19) because consistent empirical evidence is lacking (see section above, e.g., Raymo et.al. 2015 ). Further, Coleman (2004 , pp14–15) points out that a transition “should be complete and irreversible… (and) … shared by most individuals in a population”. It is a change “between one long term sustainable demographic pattern and another”. Coleman challenges the view that all aspects of the SDT are new (see also Cliquet 1991 ; Bailey et al 2013 ; Van Bavel and Reher 2013 ) and questions whether the changes we observe are complete and irreversible. Coleman raises these issues citing empirical patterns that do not conform to the SDT (as we do for some trends above).

But we raise a more fundamental criticism: this search for developmental stages and irreversible transitions is wrongheaded. Such developmental theories generally fall victim to three interrelated problems: reliance on cross-sectional data, an expectation of common processes and patterns of change, and the description of the “end state” as the most developed western society. Thornton’s (2001 ; 2005) critique of developmental theories (of the family) and “reading history sideways” apply (see 2005 pp.104–107). Note that the original SDT statements were clearly an exercise in examining cross-sectional data and interpreting differences observed as if they represented longitudinal change, i.e., reading history sideways (see Thornton’s [2005 pp. 116–17] discussion of Inglehart’s work that is a foundation of the SDT). The SDT places countries into groups of ‘leaders’ and ‘laggards’ depending on how far along they are in a predetermined set of stages (e.g., Lesthaeghe 1995 ). And the end state of the development process is best exemplified by the country most accepting of postmodern values.

Let us be specific about the negative consequence of each problem. First, interpreting cross-sectional data as representing longitudinal change requires strong assumptions that should be the focus of inquiry. Rather than looking at context-specific histories, the SDT relies heavily on widely available cross-sectional data showing national-level demographic indicators. If one assumes a uniform pattern of societal change, then these cross-sectional data can be used to construct the “stages” of the SDT (see Surkyn and Lesthaeghe 2004 ). Even as early as 1993, van de Kaa recognized that it was problematic to force “a multi-dimensional reality into a linear, sequential framework” ( van de Kaa 1994 ). However, this did not lead to significant revisions of the SDT.

Second, assuming similar processes and patterns of social change is almost always empirically inaccurate. Developmental theories posit a universal explanation for demographic patterns across times, places, and cultures (for critiques see Johnson-Hanks 2008 ; Riley and McCarthy 2003 ; Rivkin-Fish 2003 ). The SDT sees postmodern values as a powerful “exogenous” force with consistent effects worldwide. This search for a universal explanation assumes that changes in the meanings and practices surrounding reproduction and family formation occur in patterns shared across cultures. Changes in demographic rates are seen as indicators of progress in the universal transition toward modernization (now postmodernism) ( Rivkin-Fish 2003 ). However, an immense literature reveals that the assumptions of modernization stages are historically naïve (e.g., Handwerker, 1986 ; Thornton 2001 ; McCann 2009 ). As a specific example, Lesthaeghe and Neidert (2006) make the case that U.S family patterns are a “textbook example” of (and not an exception to) the SDT. They acknowledge that the SDT is less visible/powerful in the “Midwest, the Great Plains, and the South”. They attribute this to lower levels of education and less secularization in these areas and suggest that SDT changes will come to these areas soon (p. 694). But these regional patterns are now etched into the U.S. political/cultural divide (the Red vs. Blue phenomenon) and show no signs of wear (see Morgan 2011 ; 2015 ). Is it useful to view these 21st century U.S. regional differences as backwardness and as a temporary phenomenon?

And third, assumptions about the order of transitions and the end state are frequently driven by ethnocentric biases, as opposed to sound theory ( McCann 2009 ). We fear that the SDT reinforces and furthers fundamentally ethnocentric interpretations. We know that the SDT was based upon White-European family experience and that its most advanced form is posited to be emerging in western populations most accepting of postmodern values (e.g., Nordic countries). Examples of this can be seen in the exclusion of “the ethnic component” from national fertility and family indicators when searching for empirical evidence of the SDT ( Lesthaeghe 2010 , pp. 216), or as stated above, in making regional exceptions to create “textbook examples” ( Lesthaeghe and Neidert 2006 ). This exercise assigns value judgements to difference. Is it true that all people value what white Europeans do?

In sum, reading history sideways does not, in and of itself, refute the SDT theory; it only indicates that the empirical underpinnings are weak. But in theory construction, van de Kaa and Lesthaeghe chose the kind of broad, ethnocentric explanations that have attracted many sociologists and demographers in the past – grand theories of sequential, developmental change driven by a single powerful force inexorably leading to an end stage. This end stage is approximated by the current patterns in countries seen as “most advanced”.

B. Gender systems given the short shrift

Bernhardt (2004) has argued that inattention to gender is one of the main shortcomings of the SDT (also see Arpino 2014 ; García-Manglano et al 2014 ; McDonald 2000 ; Solsona 1998 ). She points out that individual autonomy and self-actualization are not gender-neutral concepts; they hold different meanings and implications for men and women. Thus, the consequences of women’s increasing self-actualization and individualism are more consequential for family change than men’s shifts to higher-order preferences ( Bernhardt 2004 ; see Solsona 1998 for a substantive example).

While SDT largely understates the role of gender change, competing theories have assigned it a pivotal role in explanatory models of fertility and family change ( Goldscheider et al 2015 ; Esping-Anderson and Billari 2014; Mason 2001 ; McDonald 2000 ; Chenais 1996). For instance, McDonald (2000) distinguished between gender equity in family-oriented and individual-oriented institutions, a distinction crucial for understanding not just the transition from high to low fertility but also the decline to lowest-low fertility. In line with Lesthaeghe’s argument that the first transition involved changes in the private sphere, McDonald (2000) asserts that that the shift from high to low fertility is primarily due to slow improvements in gender equity within family-oriented institutions followed by rapid increases in gender equity in individual-oriented institutions like the education and labor market systems, particularly in Western nations. However, the rapid increase or ‘revolution’ in the individual-oriented institutions, without complimentary and continued shifts in the family institutions leads to very low fertility. Goldscheider (2000) makes a similar argument for family formation patterns; much of the decline in marriage, as seen by increases in both divorce and cohabitation, can be attributed to the gender asymmetry in responsibilities (equal share of economic tasks but unequal share of domestic tasks).

Esping-Andersen and Billari (2015) offer another framework centered on gender-equity regimes. They suggest a longer-term developmental perspective when trying to understand fertility change, and argue that recent changes are an extension of the (first) demographic transition: following the DT first three stages ( i . high vital rates, ii. declining fertility and a slower fertility decline and iii, low vital rates), countries will experience below replacement fertility in phase iv and will show recuperation from very low fertility in phase v. The shift from phase iv to v is explained by the “gender equity catch-up” (pp.394). In this framework persistently low fertility is explained by the lag in public and private gender equity (work-family conflicts), and recuperation occurs because of what they call a “gender-equity dividend” – a relative scarcity of marriageable women relative to men that facilitate greater gender equity (pp.393).

As a final example, Goldscheider et. al (2015) explicitly offers a gender framework as an SDT competitor. Their approach predicts the recuperation of fertility to replacement levels and greater union stability. The gist of the argument is that there are “two halves” of the gender revolution. “Structural changes” in women’s roles in the public sphere (employment), i.e., in the first half of the gender revolution, have disrupted traditional gender relationships producing the “negative trends in fertility and union stability identified by the SDT” ( Goldscheider 2015 , pp. 229). The second half of the gender revolution, a change that is at best partial in many countries, involves changes in men’s roles. These changes, viewed as inevitable by Goldscheider et.al will produce a more equitable division of parenting and household labor. These changes in turn will increase fertility and union stability (see Miettinen et al 2011 for an empirical example).

These gender-based correctives have their own problems. For one, they beg the question: what causes gender change? Second, they assume that all women are able to find men with egalitarian views and substantial earning-potential, the likelihood of which is higher among the more educated group/class ( Cherlin 2016 ). It is problematic to replace one unilinear/convergence explanation with another.

C. The import of globalization

Mills and Blossfeld (2013) argue that globalization has critical implications for understanding recent decades of family and fertility change and that the SDT has ignored this powerful set of forces (see also Esping-Anderson 1999 ). Globalization theory ( Blossfeld et al 2005 ) offers a structural explanation based on four pillars: the declining importance of national borders for economic transactions; accelerated global interconnectedness through the IT revolution; tougher tax competition between countries accompanied by deregulation and privatization; and the exposure to an increasingly volatile global market. These four shifts, experienced across the globe, have led to high levels of life course uncertainty, including economic, temporal, and employment-related uncertainties. For instance, the young adult population is increasingly vulnerable to labor market uncertainty, which has contributed to postponement of life transitions, including entry into partnerships and parenthood.

One of the key factors distinguishing globalization theory from SDT theory is the importance it attributes to the role of domestic path-dependent institutions in filtering uncertainty, often unequally across different social groups. The major institutions at play include the nation’s welfare regime, employment system, and education system. Cross-national differences in family patterns and fertility levels are accounted for by differences in these three institutions. Countries with social-democratic regimes (e.g., Sweden) make the transition to partnership and parenthood easier than conservative welfare systems (e.g. Germany) relying on male breadwinner model. When men in these latter societies face labor market uncertainty, they are likely to postpone family transitions. Similarly, countries with open employment systems are able to mitigate and distribute uncertainty differently from those with closed employment systems. Educational systems differ in the amount of time spent in schools, the relative importance given to qualification versus ability-based learning, standardization, and links to labor market entry. These factors in turn influence the degree to which young people face uncertainty. The forces of globalization exacerbate inequality by offering more opportunities to better-educated youth.

Inequality is a central tenet of the globalization framework, whereas the SDT is relatively silent on this topic. The SDT silence on inequality and it emphasis on ideology suggest that all individuals have the agency and power to exercise individual freedom, achieve self-actualization and shape their life course. Under the globalization framework, institutional incompatibility of combining work and family, particularly in the context of labor market uncertainty is the driving force behind changes in family and fertility. The globalization framework does not imply unilinear change or country level convergences in fertility and family patterns (like SDT and some other frameworks discussed above), rather it provides for path dependence produced by the interaction of globalization forces and country-specific institutions.

D. Critical appraisal

Above we have argued that the underlying mechanism producing the SDT (a shift to postmodern values) is not reliably present prior to expected changes (in family and fertility). But more fundamentally, we challenge the search for all-powerful exogenous forces that produce predictable stages in the unilinear movement toward an “end stage”. This end stage resembles the contemporary country with the widest acceptance of postmodern values. Van de Kaa (1994) and later Lesthaeghe (2010) do admit that the SDT’s proposed sequence of changes in family and fertility and the inter-connectedness between key components was overly rigid. In fact, Lesthaeghe recently stated that the SDT should not be taken as a “teleological grand script with a standard scenario” but rather as a “general narrative that leaves room for many sub-narratives” ( Lesthaeghe 2010 , pp.225). While this suggestion seems to resolve the “fit to data”, it begs the question “what is left” of the original theory? And what are the mechanisms and processes that drive this attenuated SDT?

We have also reviewed SDT critiques that have argued for the incorporation of gender change and globalization into the SDT. Moreover, Lesthaeghe (2014) and van de Kaa (2004) are also on record acknowledging that the forces of globalization and gender are at play. While gender change and globalization are powerful forces that must be part of any compelling explanation of recent family/fertility change, we will not make great strides forward by rejecting the SDT in favor of a theory privileging gender or globalization. Mills and Blossfeld (2013) recognize the limits of their globalization approach and suggest that integrating the SDT and globalization frameworks “offers a more coherent perspective to understand changes in family formation since the late 1960s” (pp. 29). This is a promising direction, but the path forward is not specified. How will these approaches be integrated?

What is needed is a theory with mechanisms that can incorporate the import of new ideas as well as the material conditions of life, a theory that acknowledges the “duality of structure” ( Sewell 1992 ; 2005 ). The family and fertility regime that SDT predicts is a social structure produced by the simultaneous and inseparable impact of ideas (schemas or frames in people’s brains and in the world) and materials (in the world) that promote or constrain particular behaviors. This multi-level, interactive process would produce commonly observed path dependence, i.e., variation in the rate and nature of social change. One effort in this direction is the Theory of Conjunctural Action (TCA); it adopts this duality of structure approach and applies it to family change and variation ( Johnson-Hanks et al 2011 ). TCA emerged from a consilience project that engaged many scientists; it provides an innovative framework that incorporates causal factors/processes at multiple levels of analysis. The TCA’s core argument is that social and family demographers need to conceptualize human behavior as “emerging out of construal, grounded in schemas and materials, identity and structure” (pp. 56). These TCA building blocks integrate and make inseparable ideational causal forces (including ones central to SDT) and changes in material conditions (that lie at the heart of globalization and gender frameworks).

Johnson-Hanks et.al (2011 , see Chapters 3, 4 and 5) provide several extended applications of this TCA theory of fertility and family change (also see Bachrach and Morgan 2013 ). But the TCA key components are integral to explanations of many phenomena. As a result, application of this framework (or one like it) makes social demographic work more relevant to work in other substantive domains. Likewise, insights from other domains would be more easily grasped by social demographers. The social demographer’s penchant for parsimony, at the expense of substantive plausibility, has led to overreliance on theories posing inevitable, irreversible, and unilinear change. The second demographic transition is one example; theories embracing the “duality of structure” provide flexible alternatives, ones that embrace path dependence.

V. CONCLUSION

Ron Lesthaeghe and Dirk van de Kaa offered the Second Demographic Transition (SDT) as a description of Western European, post-Baby Boom family and fertility patterns, a useful descriptive contribution. Key components were below replacement-level fertility and an increasing diversity of union types. They posited that attractive new ideas, postmodern ideas/attitudes, enabled and required these changes, claims that are suspect. Further, Lesthaeghe has expanded the geographical scope of SDT greatly in the last two decades. While, the SDT has been elaborated in the face of conflicting empirical evidence and criticisms from social demographers, it retains fundamental weaknesses -- many shared with other developmental theories popular with family sociologists and social demographers. Social demographers should explore theory not anchored in “stages” and one that does not posit a unilinear, developmental path toward some “end stage” – in the case of SDT, one assumed to look like the “advanced” Western country most accepting of postmodern values. Instead, they should adopt or develop frameworks that incorporate postmodern values as one of many, interacting sources of change.

Acknowledgments

The authors are listed in reverse-alphabetical order and share first authorship equally. We thank the following for useful discussions and comments: Andrew Cherlin, Jenna Johnson-Hanks, Charles Hirschman, Lisa Pearce, Andrew Perrin, and Arland Thornton. We alone are responsible for the paper’s statements and conclusions. This research received support from the Population Research Training Grant (T32 HD007168) and the Population Research Infrastructure Program (P2C HD050924) awarded to the Carolina Population Center at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill by the Eunice Kennedy Shriver National Institute of Child Health and Human Development.

Contributor Information

Batool Zaidi, PhD candidate, Sociology Department, The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

S. Philip Morgan, Alan Feduccia Professor, Sociology Department and Director, Carolina Population Center, The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

LITERATURE CITED

Demographic transition Activities Unit#3 AICE Environmental AS

Show preview image 1

Also included in

demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

Description

If you're seeking engaging activities to explore the demographic transition, your search ends here. This comprehensive package covers Topic #3: Managing Human Population.

Within this file, you'll discover a trio of dynamic activities:

Day #1 : Encourages students to collaborate in pairs for an interactive cut-and-glue exercise. They'll match statements to the corresponding demographic transition stage, fostering a hands-on understanding of the topic.

Day #2 : Elevates the learning experience with a spirited challenge. Students, working in groups of four, put their knowledge to the test by identifying characteristics of demographic evolution and aligning them with the appropriate stage. The first group to successfully complete this task could earn extra credit points, igniting excitement in the classroom.

Day #2/3 : Engages students in graphing data, testing their analytical skills, and encouraging critical thinking. Guided questions accompany this activity, helping students draw insights from the data.

By incorporating these activities into your curriculum you make the exploration of demographic transition both enjoyable and educational.

Let's help students AICE the Test!

Questions & Answers

Aice the test.

  • We're hiring
  • Help & FAQ
  • Privacy policy
  • Student privacy
  • Terms of service
  • Tell us what you think

IMAGES

  1. 1234.pdf

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  2. Solved Question 9 (3 points) The demographic transition is a

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  3. Demographic Transition Model Lesson GCSE

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  4. The Demographic Transition Model Worksheet Examples Pdf

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  5. week-5-demographic-critical -thinking-activity

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

  6. Demographic Transition Critical Thinking Activity.docx

    demographic transition critical thinking activity answers

VIDEO

  1. Stages of the Demographic Transition Model

  2. The Demographic Transition Model Explained

  3. The Demographic Transition Model Explained

  4. Demographic transition

  5. The Demographic Transition Model

  6. Lesson 3

COMMENTS

  1. PDF Demographic Transiton Critical Thinking Questions

    Demographic Transiton Critical Thinking Questions

  2. DTM Critical Thinking Questions-1 1 .pdf

    Demographic Transition Critical Thinking Activity Situation 1. Billy White loses his job as a grave digger. 2. Parents start to think more about family planning 3. Children are warmer in bed at night because they have more sisters and brothers. 4. There are more Golden Anniversaries being celebrated. 5. A mother sobs over the grave of her last ...

  3. PDF Thinking about Individual and Population Health

    3. Define secular change. Provide an example to illustrate your answer. 4. Summarize three phases of demographic transition. Critical Thinking Questions Scroll down for answers. 1. Consider any recent population-based campaign introduced by Health Canada or your local community (e.g., flu vaccines, etc.).

  4. Demographic transition stages Flashcards

    stage 1 of demographic transition. very high CBR and CDR, very NIR, this is the stage for most of human history. stage 2 of demographic transition. High growth; Rapidly declining death rates and very high birth rates = very high NIR; Industrial societies or societies that benefit from the medical revolution. stage 3 of demographic transition.

  5. The Demographic Transition: A Contemporary Look at a Classic Model

    The classic Demographic Transition Model is based on the experience of Western Europe, in particular England and Wales. Critics of the model argue that "demographic transition" is a European phenomenon and not necessarily relevant to the experience of other regions, especially those regions referred to as "less developed" or ...

  6. What is the Demographic Transition Model?

    Demographic Transition Model Case Studies. Over a series of five posts we will explain each stage of the Demographic Transition Model in depth and provide a case study for stages when there is a country that currently fits its parameters. Demographic Transition Model blog series: Overview, Stage 1, Stage 2, Stage 3, Stage 4, Stage 5

  7. Demographic transition: Why is rapid population growth a temporary

    The model that explains why countries go through a period of rapid population growth is called the 'demographic transition'. It is shown in the schematic figure. It is a beautifully simple model that describes the observed pattern in countries around the world and is one of the great insights of demography. 1.

  8. 17.2E: Demographic Transition Theory

    Key Points. Demographic transition theory suggests that populations grow along a predictable five-stage model. In stage 1, pre-industrial society, death rates and birth rates are high and roughly in balance, and population growth is typically very slow and constrained by the available food supply. In stage 2, that of a developing country, the ...

  9. Eleventh grade Lesson Demographic transition

    Students need to understand the basic ideas of the demographic transition model in order to provide evidence-based claims that describe why human population pyramids differ and how population pyramids will change over time. This lesson provides a powerful analytic framework. Students will use it to make sense of human population growth over time.

  10. Demographic Transition Theories

    Definition. The theory of the demographic transition describes changes in population trends from high mortality and fertility to low mortality and fertility rates and provides explanations for the transition from economic, social, cultural, and historical perspectives. During the demographic transition, a population changes in size, age ...

  11. Demographic Transition Critical Thinking Activity.docx

    Demographic Transition Critical Thinking Activity Situation Stage Explain/Justify 1. Billy White loses his job as a grave digger Stage 2 The population is increasing but the death is decreasing so people are laid of 2.

  12. Demographic Transition

    Demographic transition is a long-term trend of declining birth and death rates, resulting in substantive change in the age distribution of a population. Population age and gender distribution is mainly affected by birth and death rates, as well as other factors such as migration, economics, war, political and social change, famine, or natural disasters.

  13. Demographic transition

    Demographic transition. In demography, demographic transition is a phenomenon and theory which refers to the historical shift from high birth rates and high death rates in societies with minimal technology, education (especially of women) and economic development, to low birth rates and low death rates in societies with advanced technology ...

  14. Stages of the Demographic Transition Model Flashcards

    True. The demographic transition model describes a transition from a fairly stable population with high crude birth and death rates to a fairly stable population with low crude birth and death rates. Study with Quizlet and memorize flashcards containing terms like Stage 1:, Stage 2:, Stage 3: and more.

  15. Classroom Activities for Teaching About Population Growth: Webinar

    To start the demonstration, have the Stork add one scooper (1 cup) of water to the bowl representing our planet, symbolizing people being born, or added, to our global population. Then, have the Grim Reaper remove a scooper (1/3 cup) from the same bowl, representing people dying. The Stork and the Grim Reaper continue in turn while students ...

  16. THE SECOND DEMOGRAPHIC TRANSITION THEORY: A Review and Appraisal

    A. Original statements. Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa coined the term 'second transition' in 1986; the phrase appeared in the title of the introductory chapter of a special volume (published in Dutch) on the demographic situation in low fertility countries (Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa 1986).Initially, Lesthaeghe and van de Kaa offered the second transition as a possible phenomenon (SDT was ...

  17. Demographic Transition Model

    Description. Demographic Transition Model - Activity Worksheet. Students must label the graph appropriately and plot the lines for birth rate, death rate, and total population. Answers are located in the PowerPoint presentation based on the Demographic Transition Model also available for purchase. Note: This activity is part of my Population ...

  18. DTM critical thinking.docx

    View DTM critical thinking.docx from PHYS 1404 at Lone Star College System, Woodlands. Name_Period_Date_ Chapter 2 Population Demographic Transition Critical Thinking Unit 2 Population and

  19. PDF A Classroom Activity to Illustrate the Demographic Transition

    Paul Weihe. Central College 812 University #015 Pella, IA 50219 Email: [email protected]. Abstract: A discussion of the Demographic Transition is included in many Environmental Biology or Environmental Science classes. The Demographic Transition occurs as a nation becomes more urban and wealthy, and was widely observed in the twentieth century.

  20. population and scarcity quiz Flashcards

    birth rates are high and death rates are high. Study with Quizlet and memorize flashcards containing terms like T or F: The demographic transition model shows population growth as a function of resource scarcity., T or F: The fertility rate is the average number of children born to a woman during her reproductive years, T or F: Every countries ...

  21. Demographic transition Activities Unit#3 AICE Environmental AS

    Day #2/3: Engages students in graphing data, testing their analytical skills, and encouraging critical thinking. Guided questions accompany this activity, helping students draw insights from the data. By incorporating these activities into your curriculum you make the exploration of demographic transition both enjoyable and educational.

  22. PDF CRITICAL THINKING

    It's thinking on purpose! Critical thinking involves mindful communication, problem-solving, and a freedom from bias or. About This Workbook. egocentric tendency. You can apply critical thinking to any kind of subject, problem, or situation you choose. The activity pages in the Critical Thinking Workbook are meant to be shared and explored.

  23. week-5-demographic-critical -thinking-activity.pdf

    Demographic Critical Thinking Activity Situation Stage Explanation Billy White loses his job as a gravedigger. Stage 2 The population is increasing but the death is decreasing so people are laid off. Parents start to think more about family planning. Stage 3 The birth rate is declining and people are living longer so it is more affordable and necessary. ...