• Search Search Please fill out this field.

What Is the Job Market?

  • Unemployment Rate

Example of a Job Market

The bottom line, job market: definition, measurement, example.

the job market essay

Gordon Scott has been an active investor and technical analyst or 20+ years. He is a Chartered Market Technician (CMT).

the job market essay

  • Economics Defined with Types, Indicators, and Systems
  • Economy Definition
  • History of Economics
  • Is Economics a Science?
  • Understanding Finance vs. Economics
  • Macroeconomics
  • Microeconomics
  • Four Economic Concepts
  • Law of Supply and Demand
  • Demand-Side Economics
  • Supply-Side Economics
  • Market Economy
  • Command Economy
  • Economic Value
  • Keynesian Economics
  • Social Economics
  • Economic Indicator
  • Top 10 US Economic Indicators
  • Gross Domestic Product (GDP)
  • What Is GDP and Why Is It So Important?
  • Consumer Spending
  • Retail Sales
  • Job Market CURRENT ARTICLE
  • The Top 25 Economies in the World
  • Examples of Free Market Economies
  • Is the US a Market Economy or a Mixed Economy?
  • Primary Drivers of the Chinese Economy
  • How India Makes Its Money
  • European Union (EU)
  • The German Economic Miracle
  • The Economy of the United Kingdom
  • How the North Korean Economy Works

The job market is the market in which employers search for employees and employees search for jobs. The job market is not a physical place as much as a concept demonstrating the competition and interplay between different labor forces. It is also known as the labor market .

The job market can grow or shrink depending on the demand for labor and the available supply of workers within the overall economy. Other factors which impact the market are the needs of a specific industry, the need for a particular education level or skill set, and required job functions. The job market is a significant component of any economy and is directly tied in with the demand for goods and services.

Key Takeaways

  • Employers search for employees and employees search for jobs in the job market.
  • The job market grows or shrinks based on demand for labor and the number of workers in the economy.
  • The job market is directly related to the unemployment rate, a measure of the percentage of people who aren't employed but actively seeking work.

The Job Market and the Unemployment Rate

The job market is also directly related to the unemployment rate . The unemployment rate is the percentage of people in the labor force who are not currently employed but actively seeking a job. The higher the unemployment rate, the greater the supply of labor in the overall job market.

When employers have a larger pool of applicants to choose from, they can be pickier or force down wages. Conversely, as the unemployment rate drops, employers are forced to compete more heavily for available workers. The competition for workers has the effect of increasing wages . Wages determined by the job market provide valuable information for economic analysts and those who set public policy based on the state of the overall economy.

The highest rate of unemployment in the U.S, which was documented in 1933.

During difficult economic times, unemployment tends to rise as employers may reduce their staffing numbers and create fewer new jobs, making it harder for people trying to find work. High rates of unemployment can prolong economic stagnation —a sustained period of little-to-no growth in an economy—and contribute to social upheaval, leading to the loss of opportunities for many individuals to live comfortably.

A report called the Current Population Survey can measure the state of the job market. It's a statistical survey performed every month by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics ( BLS ). The study includes a representative sample of about 60,000 homes to try and determine the unemployment rate of specific regions, earnings of those surveyed, hours the respondents worked, and many other demographic factors.

The BLS publishes regular snapshots of the job market, titled " Employment Situation Summaries ." According to the November 2023 report, total employment for non-farm payrolls rose by 199,000 for the month, and the unemployment rate—which is a lagging indicator —fell to 3.7%. Industries such as health care and government saw job gains during this time, as did manufacturing, due to return of workers from strikes. Employment in the retail sector fell.

How Big Is the U.S. Labor Market?

In October 2023, there were 168.3 million people in the civil labor force, a category that does not include active-duty military personnel, incarcerated individuals, farm workers, and government employees. As a proportion of the total population, this represented an employment participation rate of 62.8 percent.

What Does a Tight Job Market Mean?

Job markets are often referred to as being "tight." This means that there are more positions available than unemployed individuals willing to take them on. Conversely, when the unemployment rate is high but there are few job vacancies, the job market can be described as "slack" or "loose."

What Is the Job Vacancy Rate in the U.S.?

According to BLS, the job openings rate on the last business day of October 2023 was 5.3%, a slight decrease compared to the last month. Sectors that saw job decreases include health care and social assistance, finance and insurance, and real estate and rental and leasing.

The job openings rate is calculated by dividing the number of job openings by the sum of both filled and unfilled job, represented as a percentage.

The job market is a concept for understanding how employers seek employees and vice versa. It considers at the availability of jobs and workers, as well as other factors that can shape employment, such as competition for skilled workers or training requirements for employees. It's directly related to the unemployment rate, a metric that measures the number of people who aren't employed but are seeking to do so. Businesses, policymakers, and workers may all choose to follow news related to the job market, as it can be seen an important component of overall economic health.

National Bureau of Economic Research. " Annual Estimates of Unemployment in the United States, 1900-1954 ," Page 215.

Bureau of Labor Statistics. " Current Population Survey ."

Bureau of Labor Statistics. " Employment Situation Summary ."

BLS. " Economic News Release: Job Openings and Labor Turnover Summary - October 2023 ."

U.S. BLS. " Job Openings and Labor Turnover Summary ."

U.S. BLS. " Job Openings and Labor Turnover Technical Note ."

the job market essay

  • Terms of Service
  • Editorial Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Your Privacy Choices

Job Market Essays

Argumentative essay about attending college after highschool, intelligence (ai) is bad for society., written communication proposal, popular essay topics.

  • American Dream
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Black Lives Matter
  • Bullying Essay
  • Career Goals Essay
  • Causes of the Civil War
  • Child Abusing
  • Civil Rights Movement
  • Community Service
  • Cultural Identity
  • Cyber Bullying
  • Death Penalty
  • Depression Essay
  • Domestic Violence
  • Freedom of Speech
  • Global Warming
  • Gun Control
  • Human Trafficking
  • I Believe Essay
  • Immigration
  • Importance of Education
  • Israel and Palestine Conflict
  • Leadership Essay
  • Legalizing Marijuanas
  • Mental Health
  • National Honor Society
  • Police Brutality
  • Pollution Essay
  • Racism Essay
  • Romeo and Juliet
  • Same Sex Marriages
  • Social Media
  • The Great Gatsby
  • The Yellow Wallpaper
  • Time Management
  • To Kill a Mockingbird
  • Violent Video Games
  • What Makes You Unique
  • Why I Want to Be a Nurse
  • Send us an e-mail
  • Search Menu
  • Sign in through your institution
  • Browse content in A - General Economics and Teaching
  • Browse content in A1 - General Economics
  • A11 - Role of Economics; Role of Economists; Market for Economists
  • Browse content in B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches
  • Browse content in B4 - Economic Methodology
  • B49 - Other
  • Browse content in C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods
  • Browse content in C0 - General
  • C00 - General
  • C01 - Econometrics
  • Browse content in C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General
  • C10 - General
  • C11 - Bayesian Analysis: General
  • C12 - Hypothesis Testing: General
  • C13 - Estimation: General
  • C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General
  • C18 - Methodological Issues: General
  • Browse content in C2 - Single Equation Models; Single Variables
  • C21 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions
  • C23 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • C26 - Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimation
  • Browse content in C3 - Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models; Multiple Variables
  • C30 - General
  • C31 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions; Social Interaction Models
  • C32 - Time-Series Models; Dynamic Quantile Regressions; Dynamic Treatment Effect Models; Diffusion Processes; State Space Models
  • C35 - Discrete Regression and Qualitative Choice Models; Discrete Regressors; Proportions
  • Browse content in C4 - Econometric and Statistical Methods: Special Topics
  • C40 - General
  • Browse content in C5 - Econometric Modeling
  • C52 - Model Evaluation, Validation, and Selection
  • C53 - Forecasting and Prediction Methods; Simulation Methods
  • C55 - Large Data Sets: Modeling and Analysis
  • Browse content in C6 - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling
  • C63 - Computational Techniques; Simulation Modeling
  • C67 - Input-Output Models
  • Browse content in C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory
  • C71 - Cooperative Games
  • C72 - Noncooperative Games
  • C73 - Stochastic and Dynamic Games; Evolutionary Games; Repeated Games
  • C78 - Bargaining Theory; Matching Theory
  • C79 - Other
  • Browse content in C8 - Data Collection and Data Estimation Methodology; Computer Programs
  • C83 - Survey Methods; Sampling Methods
  • Browse content in C9 - Design of Experiments
  • C90 - General
  • C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior
  • C92 - Laboratory, Group Behavior
  • C93 - Field Experiments
  • C99 - Other
  • Browse content in D - Microeconomics
  • Browse content in D0 - General
  • D00 - General
  • D01 - Microeconomic Behavior: Underlying Principles
  • D02 - Institutions: Design, Formation, Operations, and Impact
  • D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles
  • D04 - Microeconomic Policy: Formulation; Implementation, and Evaluation
  • Browse content in D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics
  • D10 - General
  • D11 - Consumer Economics: Theory
  • D12 - Consumer Economics: Empirical Analysis
  • D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation
  • D14 - Household Saving; Personal Finance
  • D15 - Intertemporal Household Choice: Life Cycle Models and Saving
  • D18 - Consumer Protection
  • Browse content in D2 - Production and Organizations
  • D20 - General
  • D21 - Firm Behavior: Theory
  • D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis
  • D23 - Organizational Behavior; Transaction Costs; Property Rights
  • D24 - Production; Cost; Capital; Capital, Total Factor, and Multifactor Productivity; Capacity
  • Browse content in D3 - Distribution
  • D30 - General
  • D31 - Personal Income, Wealth, and Their Distributions
  • D33 - Factor Income Distribution
  • Browse content in D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design
  • D40 - General
  • D41 - Perfect Competition
  • D42 - Monopoly
  • D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection
  • D44 - Auctions
  • D47 - Market Design
  • D49 - Other
  • Browse content in D5 - General Equilibrium and Disequilibrium
  • D50 - General
  • D51 - Exchange and Production Economies
  • D52 - Incomplete Markets
  • D53 - Financial Markets
  • D57 - Input-Output Tables and Analysis
  • Browse content in D6 - Welfare Economics
  • D60 - General
  • D61 - Allocative Efficiency; Cost-Benefit Analysis
  • D62 - Externalities
  • D63 - Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
  • D64 - Altruism; Philanthropy
  • D69 - Other
  • Browse content in D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making
  • D70 - General
  • D71 - Social Choice; Clubs; Committees; Associations
  • D72 - Political Processes: Rent-seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior
  • D73 - Bureaucracy; Administrative Processes in Public Organizations; Corruption
  • D74 - Conflict; Conflict Resolution; Alliances; Revolutions
  • D78 - Positive Analysis of Policy Formulation and Implementation
  • Browse content in D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty
  • D80 - General
  • D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty
  • D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information; Mechanism Design
  • D83 - Search; Learning; Information and Knowledge; Communication; Belief; Unawareness
  • D84 - Expectations; Speculations
  • D85 - Network Formation and Analysis: Theory
  • D86 - Economics of Contract: Theory
  • D89 - Other
  • Browse content in D9 - Micro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • D90 - General
  • D91 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on Decision Making
  • D92 - Intertemporal Firm Choice, Investment, Capacity, and Financing
  • Browse content in E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Browse content in E0 - General
  • E00 - General
  • E01 - Measurement and Data on National Income and Product Accounts and Wealth; Environmental Accounts
  • E02 - Institutions and the Macroeconomy
  • E03 - Behavioral Macroeconomics
  • Browse content in E1 - General Aggregative Models
  • E10 - General
  • E12 - Keynes; Keynesian; Post-Keynesian
  • E13 - Neoclassical
  • Browse content in E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy
  • E20 - General
  • E21 - Consumption; Saving; Wealth
  • E22 - Investment; Capital; Intangible Capital; Capacity
  • E23 - Production
  • E24 - Employment; Unemployment; Wages; Intergenerational Income Distribution; Aggregate Human Capital; Aggregate Labor Productivity
  • E25 - Aggregate Factor Income Distribution
  • Browse content in E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles
  • E30 - General
  • E31 - Price Level; Inflation; Deflation
  • E32 - Business Fluctuations; Cycles
  • E37 - Forecasting and Simulation: Models and Applications
  • Browse content in E4 - Money and Interest Rates
  • E40 - General
  • E41 - Demand for Money
  • E42 - Monetary Systems; Standards; Regimes; Government and the Monetary System; Payment Systems
  • E43 - Interest Rates: Determination, Term Structure, and Effects
  • E44 - Financial Markets and the Macroeconomy
  • Browse content in E5 - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit
  • E50 - General
  • E51 - Money Supply; Credit; Money Multipliers
  • E52 - Monetary Policy
  • E58 - Central Banks and Their Policies
  • Browse content in E6 - Macroeconomic Policy, Macroeconomic Aspects of Public Finance, and General Outlook
  • E60 - General
  • E62 - Fiscal Policy
  • E66 - General Outlook and Conditions
  • Browse content in E7 - Macro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • E71 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on the Macro Economy
  • Browse content in F - International Economics
  • Browse content in F0 - General
  • F00 - General
  • Browse content in F1 - Trade
  • F10 - General
  • F11 - Neoclassical Models of Trade
  • F12 - Models of Trade with Imperfect Competition and Scale Economies; Fragmentation
  • F13 - Trade Policy; International Trade Organizations
  • F14 - Empirical Studies of Trade
  • F15 - Economic Integration
  • F16 - Trade and Labor Market Interactions
  • F18 - Trade and Environment
  • Browse content in F2 - International Factor Movements and International Business
  • F20 - General
  • F21 - International Investment; Long-Term Capital Movements
  • F22 - International Migration
  • F23 - Multinational Firms; International Business
  • Browse content in F3 - International Finance
  • F30 - General
  • F31 - Foreign Exchange
  • F32 - Current Account Adjustment; Short-Term Capital Movements
  • F34 - International Lending and Debt Problems
  • F35 - Foreign Aid
  • F36 - Financial Aspects of Economic Integration
  • Browse content in F4 - Macroeconomic Aspects of International Trade and Finance
  • F40 - General
  • F41 - Open Economy Macroeconomics
  • F42 - International Policy Coordination and Transmission
  • F43 - Economic Growth of Open Economies
  • F44 - International Business Cycles
  • Browse content in F5 - International Relations, National Security, and International Political Economy
  • F50 - General
  • F51 - International Conflicts; Negotiations; Sanctions
  • F52 - National Security; Economic Nationalism
  • F55 - International Institutional Arrangements
  • Browse content in F6 - Economic Impacts of Globalization
  • F60 - General
  • F61 - Microeconomic Impacts
  • F63 - Economic Development
  • Browse content in G - Financial Economics
  • Browse content in G0 - General
  • G00 - General
  • G01 - Financial Crises
  • G02 - Behavioral Finance: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in G1 - General Financial Markets
  • G10 - General
  • G11 - Portfolio Choice; Investment Decisions
  • G12 - Asset Pricing; Trading volume; Bond Interest Rates
  • G14 - Information and Market Efficiency; Event Studies; Insider Trading
  • G15 - International Financial Markets
  • G18 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • G19 - Other
  • Browse content in G2 - Financial Institutions and Services
  • G20 - General
  • G21 - Banks; Depository Institutions; Micro Finance Institutions; Mortgages
  • G22 - Insurance; Insurance Companies; Actuarial Studies
  • G23 - Non-bank Financial Institutions; Financial Instruments; Institutional Investors
  • G24 - Investment Banking; Venture Capital; Brokerage; Ratings and Ratings Agencies
  • G28 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G3 - Corporate Finance and Governance
  • G30 - General
  • G31 - Capital Budgeting; Fixed Investment and Inventory Studies; Capacity
  • G32 - Financing Policy; Financial Risk and Risk Management; Capital and Ownership Structure; Value of Firms; Goodwill
  • G33 - Bankruptcy; Liquidation
  • G34 - Mergers; Acquisitions; Restructuring; Corporate Governance
  • G38 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G4 - Behavioral Finance
  • G40 - General
  • G41 - Role and Effects of Psychological, Emotional, Social, and Cognitive Factors on Decision Making in Financial Markets
  • Browse content in G5 - Household Finance
  • G50 - General
  • G51 - Household Saving, Borrowing, Debt, and Wealth
  • Browse content in H - Public Economics
  • Browse content in H0 - General
  • H00 - General
  • Browse content in H1 - Structure and Scope of Government
  • H10 - General
  • H11 - Structure, Scope, and Performance of Government
  • Browse content in H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H20 - General
  • H21 - Efficiency; Optimal Taxation
  • H22 - Incidence
  • H23 - Externalities; Redistributive Effects; Environmental Taxes and Subsidies
  • H24 - Personal Income and Other Nonbusiness Taxes and Subsidies; includes inheritance and gift taxes
  • H25 - Business Taxes and Subsidies
  • H26 - Tax Evasion and Avoidance
  • Browse content in H3 - Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents
  • H31 - Household
  • Browse content in H4 - Publicly Provided Goods
  • H40 - General
  • H41 - Public Goods
  • H42 - Publicly Provided Private Goods
  • H44 - Publicly Provided Goods: Mixed Markets
  • Browse content in H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies
  • H50 - General
  • H51 - Government Expenditures and Health
  • H52 - Government Expenditures and Education
  • H53 - Government Expenditures and Welfare Programs
  • H54 - Infrastructures; Other Public Investment and Capital Stock
  • H55 - Social Security and Public Pensions
  • H56 - National Security and War
  • H57 - Procurement
  • Browse content in H6 - National Budget, Deficit, and Debt
  • H63 - Debt; Debt Management; Sovereign Debt
  • Browse content in H7 - State and Local Government; Intergovernmental Relations
  • H70 - General
  • H71 - State and Local Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H73 - Interjurisdictional Differentials and Their Effects
  • H75 - State and Local Government: Health; Education; Welfare; Public Pensions
  • H76 - State and Local Government: Other Expenditure Categories
  • H77 - Intergovernmental Relations; Federalism; Secession
  • Browse content in H8 - Miscellaneous Issues
  • H81 - Governmental Loans; Loan Guarantees; Credits; Grants; Bailouts
  • H83 - Public Administration; Public Sector Accounting and Audits
  • H87 - International Fiscal Issues; International Public Goods
  • Browse content in I - Health, Education, and Welfare
  • Browse content in I0 - General
  • I00 - General
  • Browse content in I1 - Health
  • I10 - General
  • I11 - Analysis of Health Care Markets
  • I12 - Health Behavior
  • I13 - Health Insurance, Public and Private
  • I14 - Health and Inequality
  • I15 - Health and Economic Development
  • I18 - Government Policy; Regulation; Public Health
  • Browse content in I2 - Education and Research Institutions
  • I20 - General
  • I21 - Analysis of Education
  • I22 - Educational Finance; Financial Aid
  • I23 - Higher Education; Research Institutions
  • I24 - Education and Inequality
  • I25 - Education and Economic Development
  • I26 - Returns to Education
  • I28 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in I3 - Welfare, Well-Being, and Poverty
  • I30 - General
  • I31 - General Welfare
  • I32 - Measurement and Analysis of Poverty
  • I38 - Government Policy; Provision and Effects of Welfare Programs
  • Browse content in J - Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Browse content in J0 - General
  • J00 - General
  • J01 - Labor Economics: General
  • J08 - Labor Economics Policies
  • Browse content in J1 - Demographic Economics
  • J10 - General
  • J12 - Marriage; Marital Dissolution; Family Structure; Domestic Abuse
  • J13 - Fertility; Family Planning; Child Care; Children; Youth
  • J14 - Economics of the Elderly; Economics of the Handicapped; Non-Labor Market Discrimination
  • J15 - Economics of Minorities, Races, Indigenous Peoples, and Immigrants; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J16 - Economics of Gender; Non-labor Discrimination
  • J18 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor
  • J20 - General
  • J21 - Labor Force and Employment, Size, and Structure
  • J22 - Time Allocation and Labor Supply
  • J23 - Labor Demand
  • J24 - Human Capital; Skills; Occupational Choice; Labor Productivity
  • Browse content in J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs
  • J30 - General
  • J31 - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
  • J33 - Compensation Packages; Payment Methods
  • J38 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J4 - Particular Labor Markets
  • J40 - General
  • J42 - Monopsony; Segmented Labor Markets
  • J44 - Professional Labor Markets; Occupational Licensing
  • J45 - Public Sector Labor Markets
  • J48 - Public Policy
  • J49 - Other
  • Browse content in J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining
  • J50 - General
  • J51 - Trade Unions: Objectives, Structure, and Effects
  • J53 - Labor-Management Relations; Industrial Jurisprudence
  • Browse content in J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers
  • J60 - General
  • J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers
  • J62 - Job, Occupational, and Intergenerational Mobility
  • J63 - Turnover; Vacancies; Layoffs
  • J64 - Unemployment: Models, Duration, Incidence, and Job Search
  • J65 - Unemployment Insurance; Severance Pay; Plant Closings
  • J68 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J7 - Labor Discrimination
  • J71 - Discrimination
  • J78 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in J8 - Labor Standards: National and International
  • J81 - Working Conditions
  • J88 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in K - Law and Economics
  • Browse content in K0 - General
  • K00 - General
  • Browse content in K1 - Basic Areas of Law
  • K14 - Criminal Law
  • K2 - Regulation and Business Law
  • Browse content in K3 - Other Substantive Areas of Law
  • K31 - Labor Law
  • Browse content in K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior
  • K40 - General
  • K41 - Litigation Process
  • K42 - Illegal Behavior and the Enforcement of Law
  • Browse content in L - Industrial Organization
  • Browse content in L0 - General
  • L00 - General
  • Browse content in L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance
  • L10 - General
  • L11 - Production, Pricing, and Market Structure; Size Distribution of Firms
  • L13 - Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets
  • L14 - Transactional Relationships; Contracts and Reputation; Networks
  • L15 - Information and Product Quality; Standardization and Compatibility
  • L16 - Industrial Organization and Macroeconomics: Industrial Structure and Structural Change; Industrial Price Indices
  • L19 - Other
  • Browse content in L2 - Firm Objectives, Organization, and Behavior
  • L21 - Business Objectives of the Firm
  • L22 - Firm Organization and Market Structure
  • L23 - Organization of Production
  • L24 - Contracting Out; Joint Ventures; Technology Licensing
  • L25 - Firm Performance: Size, Diversification, and Scope
  • L26 - Entrepreneurship
  • Browse content in L3 - Nonprofit Organizations and Public Enterprise
  • L33 - Comparison of Public and Private Enterprises and Nonprofit Institutions; Privatization; Contracting Out
  • Browse content in L4 - Antitrust Issues and Policies
  • L40 - General
  • L41 - Monopolization; Horizontal Anticompetitive Practices
  • L42 - Vertical Restraints; Resale Price Maintenance; Quantity Discounts
  • Browse content in L5 - Regulation and Industrial Policy
  • L50 - General
  • L51 - Economics of Regulation
  • Browse content in L6 - Industry Studies: Manufacturing
  • L60 - General
  • L62 - Automobiles; Other Transportation Equipment; Related Parts and Equipment
  • L63 - Microelectronics; Computers; Communications Equipment
  • L66 - Food; Beverages; Cosmetics; Tobacco; Wine and Spirits
  • Browse content in L7 - Industry Studies: Primary Products and Construction
  • L71 - Mining, Extraction, and Refining: Hydrocarbon Fuels
  • L73 - Forest Products
  • Browse content in L8 - Industry Studies: Services
  • L81 - Retail and Wholesale Trade; e-Commerce
  • L83 - Sports; Gambling; Recreation; Tourism
  • L84 - Personal, Professional, and Business Services
  • L86 - Information and Internet Services; Computer Software
  • Browse content in L9 - Industry Studies: Transportation and Utilities
  • L91 - Transportation: General
  • L93 - Air Transportation
  • L94 - Electric Utilities
  • Browse content in M - Business Administration and Business Economics; Marketing; Accounting; Personnel Economics
  • Browse content in M1 - Business Administration
  • M11 - Production Management
  • M12 - Personnel Management; Executives; Executive Compensation
  • M14 - Corporate Culture; Social Responsibility
  • Browse content in M2 - Business Economics
  • M21 - Business Economics
  • Browse content in M3 - Marketing and Advertising
  • M31 - Marketing
  • M37 - Advertising
  • Browse content in M4 - Accounting and Auditing
  • M42 - Auditing
  • M48 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in M5 - Personnel Economics
  • M50 - General
  • M51 - Firm Employment Decisions; Promotions
  • M52 - Compensation and Compensation Methods and Their Effects
  • M53 - Training
  • M54 - Labor Management
  • Browse content in N - Economic History
  • Browse content in N0 - General
  • N00 - General
  • N01 - Development of the Discipline: Historiographical; Sources and Methods
  • Browse content in N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Industrial Structure; Growth; Fluctuations
  • N10 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N11 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N12 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N13 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N17 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N2 - Financial Markets and Institutions
  • N20 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N22 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N23 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N3 - Labor and Consumers, Demography, Education, Health, Welfare, Income, Wealth, Religion, and Philanthropy
  • N30 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N31 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N32 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N33 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N34 - Europe: 1913-
  • N36 - Latin America; Caribbean
  • N37 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N4 - Government, War, Law, International Relations, and Regulation
  • N40 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N41 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N42 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N43 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N44 - Europe: 1913-
  • N45 - Asia including Middle East
  • N47 - Africa; Oceania
  • Browse content in N5 - Agriculture, Natural Resources, Environment, and Extractive Industries
  • N50 - General, International, or Comparative
  • N51 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N6 - Manufacturing and Construction
  • N63 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N7 - Transport, Trade, Energy, Technology, and Other Services
  • N71 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N8 - Micro-Business History
  • N82 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • Browse content in N9 - Regional and Urban History
  • N91 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N92 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N93 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N94 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth
  • Browse content in O1 - Economic Development
  • O10 - General
  • O11 - Macroeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O12 - Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O13 - Agriculture; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Other Primary Products
  • O14 - Industrialization; Manufacturing and Service Industries; Choice of Technology
  • O15 - Human Resources; Human Development; Income Distribution; Migration
  • O16 - Financial Markets; Saving and Capital Investment; Corporate Finance and Governance
  • O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors; Shadow Economy; Institutional Arrangements
  • O18 - Urban, Rural, Regional, and Transportation Analysis; Housing; Infrastructure
  • O19 - International Linkages to Development; Role of International Organizations
  • Browse content in O2 - Development Planning and Policy
  • O23 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy in Development
  • O25 - Industrial Policy
  • Browse content in O3 - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights
  • O30 - General
  • O31 - Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives
  • O32 - Management of Technological Innovation and R&D
  • O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes
  • O34 - Intellectual Property and Intellectual Capital
  • O38 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity
  • O40 - General
  • O41 - One, Two, and Multisector Growth Models
  • O43 - Institutions and Growth
  • O44 - Environment and Growth
  • O47 - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth; Aggregate Productivity; Cross-Country Output Convergence
  • Browse content in O5 - Economywide Country Studies
  • O52 - Europe
  • O53 - Asia including Middle East
  • O55 - Africa
  • Browse content in P - Economic Systems
  • Browse content in P0 - General
  • P00 - General
  • Browse content in P1 - Capitalist Systems
  • P10 - General
  • P16 - Political Economy
  • P17 - Performance and Prospects
  • P18 - Energy: Environment
  • Browse content in P2 - Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies
  • P26 - Political Economy; Property Rights
  • Browse content in P3 - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions
  • P37 - Legal Institutions; Illegal Behavior
  • Browse content in P4 - Other Economic Systems
  • P48 - Political Economy; Legal Institutions; Property Rights; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Regional Studies
  • Browse content in P5 - Comparative Economic Systems
  • P51 - Comparative Analysis of Economic Systems
  • Browse content in Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics
  • Browse content in Q1 - Agriculture
  • Q10 - General
  • Q12 - Micro Analysis of Farm Firms, Farm Households, and Farm Input Markets
  • Q13 - Agricultural Markets and Marketing; Cooperatives; Agribusiness
  • Q14 - Agricultural Finance
  • Q15 - Land Ownership and Tenure; Land Reform; Land Use; Irrigation; Agriculture and Environment
  • Q16 - R&D; Agricultural Technology; Biofuels; Agricultural Extension Services
  • Browse content in Q2 - Renewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q25 - Water
  • Browse content in Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q32 - Exhaustible Resources and Economic Development
  • Q34 - Natural Resources and Domestic and International Conflicts
  • Browse content in Q4 - Energy
  • Q41 - Demand and Supply; Prices
  • Q48 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in Q5 - Environmental Economics
  • Q50 - General
  • Q51 - Valuation of Environmental Effects
  • Q53 - Air Pollution; Water Pollution; Noise; Hazardous Waste; Solid Waste; Recycling
  • Q54 - Climate; Natural Disasters; Global Warming
  • Q56 - Environment and Development; Environment and Trade; Sustainability; Environmental Accounts and Accounting; Environmental Equity; Population Growth
  • Q58 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R0 - General
  • R00 - General
  • Browse content in R1 - General Regional Economics
  • R11 - Regional Economic Activity: Growth, Development, Environmental Issues, and Changes
  • R12 - Size and Spatial Distributions of Regional Economic Activity
  • R13 - General Equilibrium and Welfare Economic Analysis of Regional Economies
  • Browse content in R2 - Household Analysis
  • R20 - General
  • R23 - Regional Migration; Regional Labor Markets; Population; Neighborhood Characteristics
  • R28 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in R3 - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location
  • R30 - General
  • R31 - Housing Supply and Markets
  • R38 - Government Policy
  • Browse content in R4 - Transportation Economics
  • R40 - General
  • R41 - Transportation: Demand, Supply, and Congestion; Travel Time; Safety and Accidents; Transportation Noise
  • R48 - Government Pricing and Policy
  • Browse content in Z - Other Special Topics
  • Browse content in Z1 - Cultural Economics; Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology
  • Z10 - General
  • Z12 - Religion
  • Z13 - Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology; Social and Economic Stratification
  • Advance Articles
  • Editor's Choice
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access Options
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Why Submit?
  • About The Quarterly Journal of Economics
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic
  • < Previous

Job Market Signaling

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

Michael Spence, Job Market Signaling, The Quarterly Journal of Economics , Volume 87, Issue 3, August 1973, Pages 355–374, https://doi.org/10.2307/1882010

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

1. Introduction, 355. — 2. Hiring as investment under uncertainty, 356. — 3. Applicant signaling, 358. — 4. Informational feedback and the definition of equilibrium, 359. — 5. Properties of informational equilibria: an example, 361. — 6. The informational impact of indices, 368. — Conclusions, 374.

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to Your Librarian

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1531-4650
  • Print ISSN 0033-5533
  • Copyright © 2024 President and Fellows of Harvard College
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Home — Essay Samples — Life — Job — How will the job market change in the future

test_template

How Will The Job Market Change in The Future

  • Categories: Future Impact of Technology Job

About this sample

close

Words: 457 |

Published: Jun 6, 2019

Words: 457 | Page: 1 | 3 min read

Image of Dr. Oliver Johnson

Cite this Essay

Let us write you an essay from scratch

  • 450+ experts on 30 subjects ready to help
  • Custom essay delivered in as few as 3 hours

Get high-quality help

author

Verified writer

  • Expert in: Philosophy Information Science and Technology Life

writer

+ 120 experts online

By clicking “Check Writers’ Offers”, you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy . We’ll occasionally send you promo and account related email

No need to pay just yet!

Related Essays

1 pages / 442 words

0 pages / 95 words

4 pages / 1642 words

2 pages / 1046 words

Remember! This is just a sample.

You can get your custom paper by one of our expert writers.

121 writers online

Still can’t find what you need?

Browse our vast selection of original essay samples, each expertly formatted and styled

Related Essays on Job

We live in a world, where many of us are not aware of the difference between original news and politically edited news. “We have a free press”, is just a saying. Our daily news that we read in newspapers and magazines, or the [...]

In the film “Inside Job,” Matt Damon narrated a documentary that tells us the unstable systems led the global economic crises of 2008. Since the global financial meltdown happened in 2008, it resulted in the damage to the [...]

Every social worker’s goal and mission is to improve the values of others’ lives. People in this field focus on empowering those who are living in poverty, Oppression, and are vulnerable. The NASW code of ethics is a code that [...]

Understand this as an example. Suppose there is a person who comes very good designing and is a second person to do designing. So if the person who comes to designing, designing for the other person, then the work of the other [...]

If you value healthy skin and want to help others feel confident about their appearance, then pursuing a career as a dermatologist may be right for you. A dermatologist is a type of physician or medical doctor who diagnoses and [...]

A social worker’s job is made easier and more efficient through the use of technology even though a greater part of their work is face-to-face with clients. In a world where technology use is constantly growing social workers [...]

Related Topics

By clicking “Send”, you agree to our Terms of service and Privacy statement . We will occasionally send you account related emails.

Where do you want us to send this sample?

By clicking “Continue”, you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy.

Be careful. This essay is not unique

This essay was donated by a student and is likely to have been used and submitted before

Download this Sample

Free samples may contain mistakes and not unique parts

Sorry, we could not paraphrase this essay. Our professional writers can rewrite it and get you a unique paper.

Please check your inbox.

We can write you a custom essay that will follow your exact instructions and meet the deadlines. Let's fix your grades together!

Get Your Personalized Essay in 3 Hours or Less!

We use cookies to personalyze your web-site experience. By continuing we’ll assume you board with our cookie policy .

  • Instructions Followed To The Letter
  • Deadlines Met At Every Stage
  • Unique And Plagiarism Free

the job market essay

We use cookies

to give you the best experience possible.

By continuing we’ll assume you are on board with our cookie policy

the job market essay

  • Annotated Bibliography
  • Argumentative Essay
  • Research Proposal
  • Book Report
  • Book Review
  • Article Review
  • Literature Review
  • Literary Analysis
  • PowerPoint Presentation
  • Research Paper
  • Discussion Board Post
  • PhD Dissertation
  • Term Papers
  • Excel Homework
  • Editing and Proofreading Services
  • Thesis Proposal
  • Movie Critique Paper
  • Reaction Paper
  • Poem Writing Paper
  • Scholarship Essay
  • Questions-Answers
  • Resume Paper
  • Marketing Plan Paper
  • Article Writing
  • White Paper
  • Letter Writing
  • Business Letter Writing Service
  • Motivation Letter
  • LOR Writing Service
  • Grant Proposal
  • Healthcare White Paper
  • Article Critique
  • Film Review
  • Synopsis Writing
  • Speech Writing
  • Business Plan
  • Our Affiliate Program
  • Interview Writing Help
  • IB Extended Essay
  • Blog Article Writing
  • Article Rewriting
  • Essay Outline Writing
  • Capstone Project
  • Business Report Writing
  • Formatting Service
  • Online Revision
  • Write My Questionnaire
  • Report Writing Service
  • Math Problems
  • Problem Solution Essay
  • Rate My College Essay
  • Nursing Concept Map
  • Personal Statement
  • Management Essay
  • Multiple Choice Questions and Quiz
  • Psychology Essay
  • Linguistics Essay Writing Service
  • Technology Essay Writing Service
  • Economics Homework Help
  • Summary Writing Service
  • Brochure Content Writing Services
  • Graduate Essay
  • Graduate Papers
  • Buy Expository Essay
  • Engineering Assignment Writing
  • SOP Writing Services
  • Free Essays

Toll free: 1(888)813-7462 Toll free: 1(888)603-0097

Artificial Intelligence on the Job Market

VIP Account

The Transformative Impact of Artificial Intelligence on the Job Market: An In-Depth Analysis

The rapid evolution of Artificial Intelligence (AI) has ignited a paradigm shift across various facets of human existence, none more transformative than its impact on the job market. AI, with its potential to automate tasks, enhance job roles, and reshape industries, is not only changing the way we work but also raising profound questions about the future of employment. In this extensive expository essay , we delve deep into the intricate tapestry of AI’s influence on the job market, exploring the myriad opportunities, challenges, and implications it presents.

AI-content Free

the job market essay

The Automation Revolution and Job Dynamics

The most conspicuous and immediate consequence of AI in the job market is the automation revolution. AI-powered algorithms and machines can efficiently execute routine, repetitive tasks, often outperforming humans in terms of speed and precision. This has led to the displacement of human workers in various sectors such as manufacturing, data entry, and customer service. While this automation has significantly increased operational efficiency and reduced costs for businesses, it has also led to job redundancies and stagnant wages for some.

Augmentation: AI as a Collaborative Tool

Contrary to the apprehensions of AI displacing jobs entirely, it also functions as a tool for augmentation. AI can amplify human capabilities, making workers more productive and effective. For instance, in the medical field, AI-driven diagnostics assist doctors in making more accurate assessments, while in content creation, AI tools help writers generate content more efficiently. This augmentation not only enhances job performance but also opens up new avenues for skilled workers who can effectively leverage AI as a valuable tool.

The Birth of Novel Job Roles

As AI technologies continue to evolve, they engender entirely new job roles and career trajectories. Professions like AI specialists, data scientists, and machine learning engineers are now in high demand as organizations seek individuals capable of developing, maintaining, and optimizing AI systems. Additionally, the ethical implications of AI have given rise to roles focused on ensuring that AI systems adhere to ethical and societal guidelines.

Skill Evolution and Reskilling Imperatives

The integration of AI into the workforce necessitates a reevaluation of requisite skill sets. Employees across industries are finding themselves compelled to acquire new skills to remain competitive in the job market. However, this presents a significant challenge, requiring substantial investments in education and training. Moreover, reskilling efforts must cater to the needs of workers who face displacement due to automation, equipping them with the skills necessary for emerging roles.

Book The Best Top Expert at Top- papers. com

Your order will be assigned to the most experienced writer in the relevant discipline. The highly demanded expert, one of our top-10 writers with the highest rate among the customers

TOP Writer

AI-Driven Industry Transformation

AI’s impact transcends individual sectors; it is orchestrating a metamorphosis across industries. In healthcare, AI is revolutionizing patient care through predictive analytics and image recognition. The financial sector benefits from AI by optimizing trading strategies and risk assessment. Even agriculture experiences a rejuvenation with AI-driven precision farming techniques. Understanding how AI is reshaping these sectors is critical for those navigating the evolving job market.

Redefining Work Models: The Gig Economy and Remote Work

AI is not merely altering job roles; it is redefining work models themselves. The emergence of the gig economy, characterized by short-term contracts and freelance work, has been facilitated by digital platforms and AI-driven matching algorithms. Furthermore, the COVID-19 pandemic accelerated the adoption of remote work, reliant on AI for communication and collaboration tools. These shifts carry significant implications for job stability, work-life balance, and the traditional 9-to-5 work structure.

Ethical and Societal Dimensions

As AI advances at breakneck speed, the ethical and societal dimensions take center stage. Questions regarding data privacy, algorithmic bias, and the potential for AI to perpetuate job discrimination demand thorough consideration. Ensuring the responsible development and deployment of AI is imperative to mitigate adverse impacts on the job market and society as a whole.

Navigating the Future of Work

In conclusion, AI’s influence on the job market is profound and multi-faceted. While it poses challenges such as job displacement and the need for extensive reskilling, it concurrently offers opportunities for job augmentation and the creation of novel roles. Adapting to the evolving work landscape in the age of AI is imperative for individuals, businesses, and policymakers. The future of work hinges upon our capacity to embrace innovation, prioritize education and retraining, and ensure equitable access to the benefits AI brings.

As we stand on the precipice of an AI-powered future, our collective efforts to harness innovation while addressing ethical concerns will determine whether the job market evolves into a dynamic and inclusive space. Embracing AI’s transformative potential while mitigating its challenges is the pathway to crafting a future job market that empowers workers, fosters innovation, and serves society as a whole.

person

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals
  • My Account Login
  • Explore content
  • About the journal
  • Publish with us
  • Sign up for alerts
  • Open access
  • Published: 18 January 2024

The impact of artificial intelligence on employment: the role of virtual agglomeration

  • Yang Shen   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-6781-6915 1 &
  • Xiuwu Zhang 1  

Humanities and Social Sciences Communications volume  11 , Article number:  122 ( 2024 ) Cite this article

48k Accesses

3 Citations

16 Altmetric

Metrics details

  • Development studies

Sustainable Development Goal 8 proposes the promotion of full and productive employment for all. Intelligent production factors, such as robots, the Internet of Things, and extensive data analysis, are reshaping the dynamics of labour supply and demand. In China, which is a developing country with a large population and labour force, analysing the impact of artificial intelligence technology on the labour market is of particular importance. Based on panel data from 30 provinces in China from 2006 to 2020, a two-way fixed-effect model and the two-stage least squares method are used to analyse the impact of AI on employment and to assess its heterogeneity. The introduction and installation of artificial intelligence technology as represented by industrial robots in Chinese enterprises has increased the number of jobs. The results of some mechanism studies show that the increase of labour productivity, the deepening of capital and the refinement of the division of labour that has been introduced into industrial enterprises through the introduction of robotics have successfully mitigated the damaging impact of the adoption of robot technology on employment. Rather than the traditional perceptions of robotics crowding out labour jobs, the overall impact on the labour market has exerted a promotional effect. The positive effect of artificial intelligence on employment exhibits an inevitable heterogeneity, and it serves to relatively improves the job share of women and workers in labour-intensive industries. Mechanism research has shown that virtual agglomeration, which evolved from traditional industrial agglomeration in the era of the digital economy, is an important channel for increasing employment. The findings of this study contribute to the understanding of the impact of modern digital technologies on the well-being of people in developing countries. To give full play to the positive role of artificial intelligence technology in employment, we should improve the social security system, accelerate the process of developing high-end domestic robots and deepen the reform of the education and training system.

Similar content being viewed by others

the job market essay

Systematic review and meta-analysis of ex-post evaluations on the effectiveness of carbon pricing

the job market essay

The role of artificial intelligence in achieving the Sustainable Development Goals

the job market essay

Participatory action research

Introduction.

Ensuring people’s livelihood requires diligence, but diligence is not scarce. Diversification, technological upgrading, and innovation all contribute to achieving the Sustainable Development Goal of full and productive employment for all (SDGs 8). Since the outbreak of the industrial revolution, human society has undergone four rounds of technological revolution, and each technological change can be regarded as the deepening of automation technology. The conflict and subsequent rebalancing of efficiency and employment are constantly being repeated in the process of replacing people with machines (Liu 2018 ; Morgan 2019 ). When people realize the new wave of human economic and social development that is created by advanced technological innovation, they must also accept the “creative destruction” brought by the iterative renewal of new technologies (Michau 2013 ; Josifidis and Supic 2018 ; Forsythe et al. 2022 ). The questions of where technology will eventually lead humanity, to what extent artificial intelligence will change the relationship between humans and work, and whether advanced productivity will lead to large-scale structural unemployment have been hotly debated. China has entered a new stage of deep integration and development of the “new technology cluster” that is represented by the internet and the real economy. Physical space, cyberspace, and biological space have become fully integrated, and new industries, new models, and new forms of business continue to emerge. In the process of the vigorous development of digital technology, its characteristics in terms of employment, such as strong absorption capacity, flexible form, and diversified job demands are more prominent, and many new occupations have emerged. The new practice of digital survival that is represented by the platform economy, sharing economy, full-time economy, and gig economy, while adapting to, leading to, and innovating the transformation and development of the economy, has also led to significant changes in employment carriers, employment forms, and occupational skill requirements (Dunn 2020 ; Wong et al. 2020 ; Li et al. 2022 ).

Artificial intelligence (AI) is one of the core areas of the fourth industrial revolution, along with the transformation of the mechanical technology, electric power technology, and information technology, and it serves to promote the transformation and upgrading of the digital economy industry. Indeed, the rapid iteration and cross-border integration of general information technology in the era of the digital economy has made a significant contribution to the stabilization of employment and the promotion of growth, but this is due only to the “employment effect” caused by the ongoing development of the times and technological progress in the field of social production. Digital technology will inevitably replace some of the tasks that were once performed by human labour. In recent years, due to the influence of China’s labour market and employment structure, some enterprises have needed help in recruiting workers. Driven by the rapid development of artificial intelligence technology, some enterprises have accelerated the pace of “machine replacement,” resulting in repetitive and standardized jobs being performed by robots. Deep learning and AI enable machines and operating systems to perform more complex tasks, and the employment prospects of enterprise employees face new challenges in the digital age. According to the Future of Jobs 2020 report released by the World Economic Forum, the recession caused by the COVID-19 pandemic and the rapid development of automation technology are changing the job market much faster than expected, and automation and the new division of labour between humans and machines will disrupt 85 million jobs in 15 industries worldwide over the next five years. The demand for skilled jobs, such as data entry, accounting, and administrative services, has been hard hit. Thanks to the wave of industrial upgrading and the vigorous development of digitalization, the recruitment demand for AI, big data, and manufacturing industries in China has maintained high growth year-on-year under the premise of macroenvironmental uncertainty during the period ranging from 2019 to 2022, and the average annual growth rate of new jobs was close to 30%. However, this growth has also aggravated the sense of occupational crisis among white-collar workers. The research shows that the agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, fishery, mining, manufacturing, and construction industries, which are expected to adopt a high level of intelligence, face a high risk of occupational substitution, and older and less educated workers are faced with a very high risk of substitution (Wang et al. 2022 ). Whether AI, big data, and intelligent manufacturing technology, as brand-new forms of digital productivity, will lead to significant changes in the organic composition of capital and effectively decrease labour employment has yet to reach consensus. As the “pearl at the top of the manufacturing crown,” a robot is an essential carrier of intelligent manufacturing and AI technology as materialized in machinery and equipment, and it is also an important indicator for measuring a country’s high-end manufacturing industry. Due to the large number of manufacturing employees in China, the challenge of “machine substitution” to the labour market is more severe than that in other countries, and the use of AI through robots is poised to exert a substantial impact on the job market (Xie et al. 2022 ). In essence, the primary purpose of the digital transformation of industrial enterprises is to improve quality and efficiency, but the relationship between machines and workers has been distorted in the actual application of digital technology. Industrial companies use robots as an entry point, and the study delves into the impact of AI on the labour market to provide experience and policy suggestions on the best ways of coordinating the relationship between enterprise intelligent transformation and labour participation and to help realize Chinese-style modernization.

As a new general technology, AI technology represents remarkable progress in productivity. Objectively analysing the dual effects of substitution and employment creation in the era of artificial intelligence to actively integrate change and adapt to development is essential to enhancing comprehensive competitiveness and better qualifying workers for current and future work. This research is organized according to a research framework from the published literature (Luo et al. 2023 ). In this study, we used data published by the International Federation of Robotics (IFR) and take the installed density of industrial robots in China as the main indicator of AI. Based on panel data from 30 provinces in China covering the period from 2006–2020, the impact of AI technology on employment in a developing country with a large population size is empirically examined. The issues that need to be solved in this study include the following: The first goal is to examine the impact of AI on China’s labour market from the perspective of the economic behaviour of those enterprises that have adopted the use of industrial robots in production. The realistic question we expect to answer is whether the automated processing of daily tasks has led to unemployment in China during the past fifteen years. The second goal is to answer the question of how AI will continue to affect the employment market by increasing labour productivity, changing the technical composition of capital, and deepening the division of labour. The third goal is to examine how the transformation of industrial organization types in the digital economy era affects employment through digital industrial clusters or virtual clusters. The fourth goal is to test the role of AI in eliminating gender discrimination, especially in regard to whether it can improve the employment opportunities of female employees. Then, whether workers face different employment difficulties in different industry attributes is considered. The final goal is to provide some policy insights into how a developing country can achieve full employment in the face a new technological revolution in the context of a large population and many low-skilled workers.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section Literature Review, we summarize the literature on the impact of AI on the labour market and employment and classify it from three perspectives: pessimistic, negative, and neutral. Based on a literature review, we then summarize the marginal contribution of this study. In Section Theoretical mechanism and research hypothesis, we provide a theoretical analysis of AI’s promotion of employment and present the research hypotheses to be tested. In Section Study design and data sources, we describe the data source, variable setting and econometric model. In Section Empirical analysis, we test Hypothesis 1 and conduct a robustness test and the causal identification of the conclusion. In Section Extensibility analysis, we test Hypothesis 2 and Hypothesis 3, as well as testing the heterogeneity of the baseline regression results. The heterogeneity test employee gender and industry attributes increase the relevance of the conclusions. Finally, Section Conclusions and policy implications concludes.

Literature review

The social effect of technological progress has the unique characteristics of the times and progresses through various stages, and there is variation in our understanding of its development and internal mechanism. A classic argument of labour sociology and labour economics is that technological upgrading objectively causes workers to lose their jobs, but the actual historical experience since the industrial revolution tells us that it does not cause large-scale structural unemployment (Zhang 2023a ). While neoclassical liberals such as Adam Smith claimed that technological progress would not lead to unemployment, other scholars such as Sismondi were adamant that it would. David Ricardo endorsed the “Luddite fear” in his book On Machinery, and Marx argued that technological progress can increase labour productivity while also excluding labour participation, thus leaving workers in poverty. The worker being turned ‘into a crippled monstrosity’ by modern machinery. Technology is not used to reduce working hours and improve the quality of work, rather, it is used to extend working hours and speed up work (Spencer 2023 ). According to Schumpeter’s innovation theory, within a unified complex system, the essence of technological innovation forms from the unity of positive and negative feedback and the oneness of opposites such as “revolutionary” and “destructive.” Even a tiny technological impact can cause drastic consequences. The impact of AI on employment is different from the that of previous industrial revolutions, and it is exceptional in that “machines” are no longer straightforward mechanical tools but have assumed more of a “worker” role, just as people who can learn and think tend to do (Boyd and Holton 2018 ). AI-related technologies continue to advance, the industrialization and commercialization process continues to accelerate, and the industry continues to explore the application of AI across multiple fields. Since AI was first proposed at the Dartmouth Conference in 1956, discussions about “AI replacing human labor” and “AI defeating humans” have endlessly emerged. This dynamic has increased in intensity since the emergence of ChatGPT, which has aroused people’s concerns about technology replacing the workforce. Summarizing the literature, we can find three main arguments concerning the relationship between AI and employment:

First, AI has the effect of creating and filling jobs. The intelligent manufacturing industry paradigm characterized by AI technology will assist in forming a high-quality “human‒machine cooperation” employment mode. In an enlightened society, the social state of shared prosperity benefits the lowest class of people precisely because of the advanced productive forces and higher labour efficiency created through the refinement of the division of labour. By improving production efficiency, reducing the sales price of final products, and stimulating social consumption, technological progress exerts both price effects and income effects, which in turn drive related enterprises to expand their production scale, which, in turn, increases the demand for labour (Li et al. 2021 ; Ndubuisi et al. 2021 ; Yang 2022 ; Sharma and Mishra 2023 ; Li et al. 2022 ). People habitually regard robots as competitors for human beings, but this view only represents the materialistic view of traditional machinery. The coexistence of man and machine is not a zero-sum game. When the task evolves from “cooperation for all” to “cooperation between man and machine,” it results in fewer production constraints and maximizes total factor productivity, thus creating more jobs and generating novel collaborative tasks (Balsmeier and Woerter 2019 ; Duan et al. 2023 ). At the same time, materialized AI technology can improve the total factor production efficiency in ways that are suitable for its factor endowment structure and improve the production efficiency between upstream and downstream enterprises in the industrial chain and the value chain. This increase in the efficiency of the entire market will subsequently drive the expansion of the production scale of enterprises and promote reproduction, and its synergy will promote the synchronous growth of the labour demand involving various skills, thus resulting in a creative effect (Liu et al. 2022 ). As an essential force in the fourth industrial revolution, AI inevitably affects the social status of humans and changes the structure of the labour force (Chen 2023 ). AI and machines increase labour productivity by automating routine tasks while expanding employee skills and increasing the value of work. As a result, in a machine-for-machine employment model, low-skilled jobs will disappear, while new and currently unrealized job roles will emerge (Polak 2021 ). We can even argue that digital technology, artificial intelligence, and robot encounters are helping to train skilled robots and raise their relative wages (Yoon 2023 ).

Second, AI has both a destructive effect and a substitution effect on employment. As soon as machines emerged as the means of labour, they immediately began to compete with the workers themselves. As a modern new technology, artificial intelligence is essentially humanly intelligent labour that condenses complex labour. Like the disruptive general-purpose technologies of early industrialization, automation technologies such as AI offer both promise and fear in regard to “machine replacement.” Technological progress leads to an increase in the organic composition of capital and the relative surplus population. The additional capital formed in capital accumulation comes to absorb fewer and fewer workers compared to its quantity. At the same time, old capital, which is periodically reproduced according to the new composition, will begin to increasingly exclude the workers it previously employed, resulting in severe “technological unemployment.” The development of productivity creates more free time, especially in industries such as health care, transportation, and production environment control, which have seen significant benefits from AI. In recent years, however, some industrialized countries have faced the dilemma of declining income from labour and the slow growth of total labour productivity while applying AI on a large scale (Autor 2019 ). Low-skilled and incapacitated workers enjoy a high probability of being replaced by automation (Ramos et al. 2022 ; Jetha et al. 2023 ). It is worth noting that with the in-depth development of digital technologies, such as deep learning and big data analysis, some complex, cognitive, and creative jobs that are currently considered irreplaceable in the traditional view will also be replaced by AI, which indicates that automation technology is not only a substitute for low-skilled labour (Zhao and Zhao 2017 ; Dixon et al. 2021 ; Novella et al. 2023 ; Nikitas et al. 2021 ). Among factors, AI and robotics exert a particularly significant impact on the manufacturing job market, and industry-related jobs will face a severe unemployment problem due to the disruptive effect of AI and robotics (Zhou and Chen 2022 ; Sun and Liu 2023 ). At this stage, most of the world’s economies are facing the deep integration of the digital wave in their national economy, and any work, including high-level tasks, is being affected by digitalization and AI (Gardberg et al. 2020 ). The power of AI models is growing exponentially rather than linearly, and the rapid development and rapid diffusion of technology will undoubtedly have a devastating effect on knowledge workers, as did the industrial revolution (Liu and Peng 2023 ). In particular, the development and improvement of AI-generated content in recent years poses a more significant threat to higher-level workers, such as researchers, data analysts, and product managers, than to physical labourers. White collar workers are facing unprecedented anxiety and unease (Nam 2019 ; Fossen and Sorgner 2022 ; Wang et al. 2023 ). A classic study suggests that AI could replace 47% of the 702 job types in the United States within 20 years (Frey and Osborne 2017 ). Since the 2020 epidemic, digitization has accelerated, and online and digital resources have become a must for enterprises. Many occupations are gradually moving away from humans (Wu and Yang 2022 ; Männasoo et al. 2023 ). It is obvious that the intelligent robot arm on the factory assembly line is poised to allow factory assembly line workers to exit the stage and move into history. Career guides are being replaced by mobile phone navigation software.

Third, the effect of AI on employment is uncertain, and its impact on human work does not fall into a simple “utopian” or “dystopian” scene, but rather leads to a combination of “utopia” and “dystopia” (Kolade and Owoseni 2022 ). The job-creation effects of robotics and the emergence of new jobs that result from technological change coexist at the enterprise level (Ni and Obashi 2021 ). Adopting a suitable AI operation mode can adjust for the misallocation of resources by the market, enterprises, and individuals to labour-intensive tasks, reverse the nondirectional allocation of robots in the labour sector, and promote their reallocation in the manufacturing and service industries. The size of the impact on employment through the whole society is uncertain (Fabo et al. 2017 ; Huang and Rust 2018 ; Berkers et al. 2020 ; Tschang and Almirall 2021 ; Reljic et al. 2021 ). For example, Oschinski and Wyonch ( 2017 ) claimed that those jobs that are easily replaced by AI technology in Canada account for only 1.7% of the total labour market, and they have yet to find evidence that automation technology will cause mass unemployment in the short term. Wang et al. ( 2022 ) posited that the impact of industrial robots on labour demand in the short term is mainly negative, but in the long run, its impact on employment is mainly that of job creation. Kirov and Malamin ( 2022 ) claimed that the pessimism underlying the idea that AI will destroy the jobs and quality of language workers on a large scale is unjustified. Although some jobs will be eliminated as such technology evolves, many more will be created in the long run.

In the view that modern information technology and digital technology increase employment, the literature holds that foreign direct investment (Fokam et al. 2023 ), economic systems (Bouattour et al. 2023 ), labour skills and structure (Yang 2022 ), industrial technological intensity (Graf and Mohamed 2024 ), and the easing of information friction (Jin et al. 2023 ) are important mechanisms. The research on whether AI technology crowds out jobs is voluminous, but the conclusions are inconsistent (Filippi et al. 2023 ). This paper is focused on the influence of AI on the employment scale of the manufacturing industry, examines the job creation effect of technological progress from the perspectives of capital deepening, labour refinement, and labour productivity, and systematically examines the heterogeneous impact of the adoption of industrial robots on employment demand, structure, and different industries. The marginal contributions of this paper are as follows: first, the installation density of industrial robots is used as an indicator to measure AI, and the question of whether AI has had negative effects on employment in the manufacturing sector from the perspective of machine replacement is examined. The second contribution is the analysis of the heterogeneity of AI’s employment creation effect from the perspective of gender and industry attributes and the claim that women and the employees of labour-intensive enterprises are more able to obtain additional work benefits in the digital era. Most importantly, in contrast to the literature, this paper innovatively introduces virtual agglomeration into the path mechanism of the effect of robots on employment and holds that information technologies such as the internet, big data, and the industrial Internet of Things, which rely upon AI, have reshaped the management mode and organizational structure of enterprises. Online and offline integration work together, and information, knowledge, and technology are interconnected. In the past, the job matching mode of one person, one post, and specific individuals has changed into a multiple faceted set of tasks involving one person, many posts, and many types of people. The internet platform spawned by digital technology frees the employment mode of enterprises from being limited to single enterprises and specific gathering areas. Traditional industrial geographical agglomeration has gradually evolved into virtual agglomeration, which geometrically enlarges the agglomeration effect and mechanism and enhances the spillover effect. In the online world, individual practitioners and entrepreneurs can obtain orders, receive training, connect resources and employment needs more widely and efficiently, and they can achieve higher-quality self-employment. Virtual agglomeration has become a new path by which AI affects employment. Another literature contribution is that this study used the linear regression model of the machine learning model in the robustness test part, which verified the employment creation effect of AI from the perspective of positive contribution proportion. In causal identification, this study innovatively uses the industrial feed-in price as a tool variable to analyse the causal path of AI promoting employment.

Theoretical mechanism and research hypothesis

The direct influence of ai on employment.

With advances in machine learning, big data, artificial intelligence, and other technologies, a new generation of intelligent robots that can perform routine, repetitive, and regular production tasks requiring human judgement, problem-solving, and analytical skills has emerged. Robotic process automation technology can learn and imitate the way that workers perform repeated new tasks regarding the collecting of data, running of reports, copying of data, checking of data integrity, reading, processing, and the sending of emails, and it can play an essential role in processing large amounts of data (Alan 2023 ). In the context of an informatics- and technology-oriented economy, companies are asking employees to transition into creative jobs. According to the theory of the combined task framework, the most significant advantage of the productivity effect produced by intelligent technology is creation of new demands, that is, the creation of new tasks (Acemoglu and Restrepo 2018 ). These new task packages update the existing tasks and create new task combinations with more complex technical difficulties. Although intelligent technology is widely used in various industries, it may have a substitution effect on workers and lead to technical unemployment. However, with the rise of a new round of technological innovation and revolution, high efficiency leads to the development and growth of a series of emerging industries and exerts job creation effects. Technological progress has the effect of creating new jobs. That is, such progress creates new jobs that are more in line with the needs of social development and thus increases the demand for labour (Borland and Coelli 2017 ). Therefore, the intelligent development of enterprises will come to replace their initial programmed tasks and produce more complex new tasks, and human workers in nonprogrammed positions, such as technology and knowledge, will have more comparative advantages.

Generally, the “new technology-economy” paradigm that is derived from automation machine and AI technology is affecting the breadth and depth of employment, which is manifested as follows:

It reduces the demand for coded jobs in enterprises while increasing the demand for nonprogrammed complex labour.

The development of digital technology has deepened and refined the division of labour, accelerated the service trend of the manufacturing industry, increased the employment share of the modern service industry and created many emerging jobs.

Advanced productive forces give workers higher autonomy and increased efficiency in their work, improving their job satisfaction and employment quality. As described in Das Kapital, “Although machines actually crowd out and potentially replace a large number of workers, with the development of machines themselves (which is manifested by the increase in the number of the same kind of factories or the expansion of the scale of existing factories), the number of factory workers may eventually be more than the number of handicraft workers in the workshops or handicrafts that they crowd out… It can be seen that the relative reduction and absolute increase of employed workers go hand in hand” (Li and Zhang 2022 ).

Internet information technology reduces the distance between countries in both time and space, promotes the transnational flow of production factors, and deepens the international division of labour. The emergence of AI technology leads to the decline of a country’s traditional industries and departments. Under the new changes to the division of labour, these industries and departments may develop in late-developing countries and serve to increase their employment through international labour export.

From a long-term perspective, AI will create more jobs through the continuous expansion of the social production scale, the continuous improvement of production efficiency, and the more detailed industrial categories that it engenders. With the accumulation of human capital under the internet era, practitioners are gradually becoming liberated from heavy and dangerous work, and workers’ skills and job adaptability will undergo continuous improvement. The employment creation and compensation effects caused by technological and industrial changes are more significant than the substitution effects (Han et al. 2022 ). Accordingly, the article proposes the following two research hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1 (H1): AI increases employment .

Hypothesis 2 (H2): AI promotes employment by improving labour productivity, deepening capital, and refining the division of labour .

Role of virtual agglomeration

The research on economic geography and “new” economic geography agglomeration theory focuses on industrial agglomeration in the traditional sense. This model is a geographical agglomeration model that depends on spatial proximity from a geographical perspective. Assessing the role of externalities requires a particular geographical scope, as it has both physical and scope limitations. Virtual agglomeration transcends Marshall’s theory of economies of scale, which is not limited to geographical agglomeration from the perspective of natural territory but rather takes on more complex and multidimensional forms (such as virtual clusters, high-tech industrial clusters, and virtual business circles). Under the influence of a new generation of digital technology that is characterized by big data, the Internet of Things, and the industrial internet, the digital, intelligent, and platform transformation trend is prominent in some industries and enterprises, and industrial digitalization and digital industrialization jointly promote industrial upgrading. The innovation of information technology leads to “distance death” (Schultz 1998 ). With the further materialization of digital and networked services of enterprises, the trading mode of digital knowledge and services, such as professional knowledge, information combination, cultural products, and consulting services, has transitioned from offline to digital trade, and the original geographical space gathering mode between enterprises has gradually evolved into a virtual network gathering that places the real-time exchange of data and information as its core (Wang et al. 2018 ). Tan and Xia ( 2022 ) stated that virtual agglomeration geometrically magnifies the social impact of industrial agglomeration mechanisms and agglomeration effects, and enterprises in the same industry and their upstream and downstream affiliated enterprises can realize low-cost long-distance transactions, services, and collaborative production through digital trade, resulting in large-scale zero-distance agglomeration along with neighbourhood-style production, service, circulation, and consumption. First, the knowledge and information underlying the production, design, research and development, organization, and trading of all kinds of enterprises are increasingly being completed by digital technology. The tacit knowledge that used to require face-to-face communication has become codable, transmissible, and reproducible under digital technology. Tacit knowledge has gradually become explicit, and knowledge spillover and technology diffusion have become more pronounced, which further leads to an increase in the demand for unconventional task labour (Zhang and Li 2022 ). Second, the cloud platform causes the labour pool effect of traditional geographical agglomeration to evolve into the labour “conservation land” of virtual agglomeration, and employment is no longer limited to the internal organization or constrained within a particular regional scope. Digital technology allows enterprises to hire “ghost workers” for lower wages to compensate for the possibility of AI’s “last mile.” Information technology and network platforms seek connections with all social nodes, promoting the time and space for work in a way that transcends standardized fixed frameworks. At the same time, joining or quitting work tasks, indirectly increasing the temporary and transitional nature of work and forming a decentralized management organization model of supplementary cooperation, social networks, industry experts, and skilled labour all become more convenient for workers (Wen and Liu 2021 ). With a mobile phone and a computer, labourers worldwide can create value for enterprises or customers, and the forms of labour are becoming more flexible and diverse. Workers can provide digital real-time services to employers far away from their residence, and they can also obtain flexible employment information and improve their digital skills through the leveraging of digital resources, resulting in the odd-job economy, crowdsourcing economy, sharing economy, and other economic forms. Finally, the network virtual space can accommodate almost unlimited enterprises simultaneously. In the commercial background of digital trade, while any enterprise can obtain any intermediate supply in the online market, its final product output can instantly become the intermediate input of other enterprises. Therefore, enterprises’ raw material supply and product sales rely on the whole market. At this time, the market scale effect of intermediate inputs can be infinitely amplified, as it is no longer confined to the limited space of geographical agglomeration (Duan and Zhang 2023 ). Accordingly, the following research hypothesis is proposed:

Hypothesis 3 (H3): AI promotes employment by improving the VA of enterprises .

Study design and data sources

Variable setting, explained variable.

Employment scale (ES). Compared with the agriculture and service industry, the industrial sector accommodates more labour, and robot technology is mainly applied in the industrial sector, which has the greatest demand shock effect on manufacturing jobs. In this paper, we select the number of employees in manufacturing cities and towns as the proxy variable for employment scale.

Core explanatory variable

Artificial intelligence (AI). Emerging technologies endow industrial robots with more complete technical attributes, which increases their ability to act as human beings in many work projects, enabling them to either independently complete production tasks or to assist humans in completing such tasks. This represents an important form of AI technology embedded into machinery and equipment. In this paper, the installation density of industrial robots is selected as the proxy variable for AI. Robot data mainly come from the number of robots installed in various industries at various national levels as published by the International Federation of Robotics (IFR). Because the dataset published by the IFR provides the dataset at the national-industry level and its industry classification standards are significantly different from those in China, the first lessons for this paper are drawn from the practices of Yan et al. ( 2020 ), who matches the 14 manufacturing categories published by the IFR with the subsectors in China’s manufacturing sector, and then uses the mobile share method to merge and sort out the employment numbers of various industries in various provinces. First, the national subsector data provided by the IFR are matched with the second National Economic Census data. Next, the share of employment in different industries to the total employment in the province is used to develop weights and decompose the industry-level robot data into the local “provincial-level industry” level. Finally, the application of robots in various industries at the provincial level is summarized. The Bartik shift-share instrumental variable is now widely used to measure robot installation density at the city (province) level (Wu 2023 ; Yang and Shen, 2023 ; Shen and Yang 2023 ). The calculation process is as follows:

In Eq. ( 1 ), N is a collection of manufacturing industries, Robot it is the robot installation density of province i in year t, \({{{\mathrm{employ}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{ij}}}},{{{\mathrm{t}}}} = 2006}\) is the number of employees in industry j of province i in 2006, \({{{\mathrm{employ}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{i}}}},{{{\mathrm{t}}}} = 2006}\) is the total number of employees in province i in 2006, and \({{{\mathrm{Robot}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{jt}}}}}{{{\mathrm{/employ}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{i}}}},{{{\mathrm{t}}}} = 2006}\) represents the robot installation density of each year and industry level.

Mediating variables

Labour productivity (LP). According to the definition and measurement method proposed by Marx’s labour theory of value, labour productivity is measured by the balance of the total social product minus the intermediate goods and the amount of labour consumed by the pure production sector. The specific calculation process is \(AL = Y - k/l\) , where Y represents GDP, l represents employment, k represents capital depreciation, and AL represents labour productivity. Capital deepening (CD). The per capita fixed capital stock of industrial enterprises above a designated size is used in this study as a proxy variable for capital deepening. The division of labour refinement (DLR) is refined and measured by the number of employees in producer services. Virtual agglomeration (VA) is mainly a continuation of the location entropy method in the traditional industrial agglomeration measurement idea, and weights are assigned according to the proportion of the number of internet access ports in the country. Because of the dependence of virtual agglomeration on digital technology and network information platforms, the industrial agglomeration degree of each region is first calculated in this paper by using the number of information transmissions, computer services, and software practitioners and then multiplying that number by the internet port weight. The specific expression is \(Agg_{it} = \left( {M_{it}/M_t} \right)/\left( {E_{it}/E_t} \right) \times \left( {Net_{it}/Net_t} \right)\) , where \(M_{it}\) represents the number of information transmissions, computer services and software practitioners in region i in year t, \(M_t\) represents the total number of national employees in this industry, \(E_{it}\) represents the total number of employees in region i, \(E_t\) represents the total number of national employees, \(Net_{it}\) represents the number of internet broadband access ports in region i, and \(Net_t\) represents the total number of internet broadband access ports in the country. VA represents the degree of virtual agglomeration.

Control variables

To avoid endogeneity problems caused by unobserved variables and to obtain more accurate estimation results, seven control variables were also selected. Road accessibility (RA) is measured by the actual road area at the end of the year. Industrial structure (IS) is measured by the proportion of the tertiary industry’s added value and the secondary industry’s added value. The full-time equivalent of R&D personnel is used to measure R&D investment (RD). Wage cost (WC) is calculated using city average salary as a proxy variable; Marketization (MK) is determined using Fan Gang marketization index as a proxy variable; Urbanization (UR) is measured by the proportion of the urban population to the total population at the end of the year; and the proportion of general budget expenditure to GDP is used to measure Macrocontrol (MC).

Econometric model

To investigate the impact of AI on employment, based on the selection and definition of the variables detailed above and by mapping the research ideas to an empirical model, the following linear regression model is constructed:

In Eq. ( 2 ), ES represents the scale of manufacturing employment, AI represents artificial intelligence, and subscripts t, i and m represent time t, individual i and the m th control variable, respectively. \(\mu _i\) , \(\nu _t\) and \(\varepsilon _{it}\) represent the individual effect, time effect and random disturbance terms, respectively. \(\delta _0\) is the constant term, a is the parameter to be fitted, and Control represents a series of control variables. To further test whether there is a mediating effect of mechanism variables in the process of AI affecting employment, only the influence of AI on mechanism variables is tested in the empirical part according to the modelling process and operational suggestions of the intermediary effects as proposed by Jiang ( 2022 ) to overcome the inherent defects of the intermediary effects. On the basis of Eq. ( 2 ), the following econometric model is constructed:

In Eq. ( 3 ), Media represents the mechanism variable. β 1 represents the degree of influence of AI on mechanism variables, and its significance and symbolic direction still need to be emphasized. The meanings of the remaining symbols are consistent with those of Eq. ( 2 ).

Data sources

Following the principle of data availability, the panel data of 30 provinces (municipalities and autonomous regions) in China from 2006 to 2020 (samples from Tibet and Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan were excluded due to data availability) were used as statistical investigation samples. The raw data on the installed density of industrial robots and the number of workers in the manufacturing industry come from the International Federation of Robotics and the China Labour Statistics Yearbook. The original data for the remaining indicators came from the China Statistical Yearbook, China Population and Employment Statistical Yearbook, China’s Marketization Index Report by Province (2021), the provincial and municipal Bureau of Statistics, and the global statistical data analysis platform of the Economy Prediction System (EPS). The few missing values are supplemented through linear interpolation. It should be noted that although the IFR has yet to release the number of robots installed at the country-industry level in 2020, it has published the overall growth rate of new robot installations, which is used to calculate the robot stock in 2020 for this study. The descriptive statistical analysis of relevant variables is shown in Table 1 .

Empirical analysis

To reduce the volatility of the data and address the possible heteroscedasticity problem, all the variables are located. The results of the Hausmann test and F test both reject the null hypothesis at the 1% level, indicating that the fixed effect model is the best-fitting model. Table 2 reports the fitting results of the baseline regression.

As shown in Table 2 , the results of the two-way fixed-effect (TWFE) model displayed in Column (5) show that the fitting coefficient of AI on employment is 0.989 and is significant at the 1% level. At the same time, the fitting results of other models show that the impact of AI on employment is significantly positive. The results confirm that the effect of AI on employment is positive and the effect of job creation is greater than the effect of destruction, and these conclusions are robust, thus verifying the employment creation mechanism of technological progress. Research Hypothesis 1 (H1) is supported. The new round of scientific and technological revolution represented by artificial intelligence involves the upgrading of traditional industries, the promotion of major changes in the economy and society, the driving of rapid development of the “unmanned economy,” the spawning a large number of new products, new technologies, new formats, and new models, and the provision of more possibilities for promoting greater and higher quality employment. Classical and neoclassical economics view the market mechanism as a process of automatic correction that can offset the job losses caused by labour-saving technological innovation. Under the premise of the “employment compensation” theory, the new products, new models, and new industrial sectors created by the progress of AI technology can directly promote employment. At the same time, the scale effect caused by advanced productivity results in lower product prices and higher worker incomes, which drives increased demand and economic growth, increasing output growth and employment (Ge and Zhao 2023 ). In conjunction with the empirical results of this paper, we have reason to believe that enterprises adopt the strategy of “machine replacement” to replace procedural and repetitive labour positions in the pursuit of high efficiency and high profits. However, AI improves not only enterprises’ production efficiency but also their production capacity and scale economy. To occupy a favourable share of market competition, enterprises expand the scale of reproduction. At this point, new and more complex tasks continue to emerge, eventually leading companies to hire more labour. At this stage, robot technology and application in developing countries are still in their infancy. Whether regarding the application scenario or the application scope of robots, the automation technology represented by industrial robots has not yet been widely promoted, which increases the time required for the automation technology to completely replace manual tasks, so the destruction effect of automation technology on jobs is not apparent. The fundamental market situation of the low cost of China’s labour market drives enterprises to pay more attention to technology upgrading and efficiency improvement when introducing industrial robots. The implementation of the machine replacement strategy is mainly caused by the labour shortage driven by high work intensity, high risk, simple process repetition, and poor working conditions. The intelligent transformation of enterprises points to more than the simple saving of labour costs (Dixon et al. 2021 ).

Robustness test

The above results show that the effect of AI on job creation is greater than the effect of substitution and the overall promotion of enterprises for the enhancement of employment demand. To verify the robustness of the benchmark results, the following three means of verifying the results are adopted in this study. First, we replace the explained variables. In addition to industrial manufacturing, robots are widely used in service industries, such as medical care, finance, catering, and education. To reflect the dynamic change relationship between the employment share of the manufacturing sector and the employment number of all sectors, the absolute number of manufacturing employees is replaced by the ratio of the manufacturing industry to all employment numbers. The second means is increasing the missing variables. Since many factors affect employment, this paper considers the living cots, human capital, population density, and union power in the basic regression model. The impact of these variables on employment is noticeable; for example, the existence of trade unions improves employee welfare and the working environment but raises the entry barrier for workers in the external market. The new missing variables are the average selling price of commercial and residential buildings, urban population density (person/square kilometre), nominal human capital stock, and the number of grassroots trade union organizations in the China Human Capital Report 2021 issued by Central University of Finance and Economics, which are used as proxy variables. The third means involves the use of linear regression (the gradient descent method) in machine learning regression to calculate the importance of AI to the increase in employment size. The machine learning model has a higher goodness of fit and fitting effect on the predicted data, and its mean square error and mean absolute error are more minor (Wang Y et al. 2022 ).

As seen from the robustness part of Table 3 , the results of Method 1 show that AI exerts a positive impact on the employment share in the manufacturing industry; that is, AI can increase the proportion of employment in the manufacturing industry, the use of AI creates more derivative jobs for the manufacturing industry, and the demand for the labour force of enterprises further increases. The results of method 2 show that after increasing the number of control variables, the influence of robots on employment remains significantly positive, indicating no social phenomenon of “machine replacement.” The results of method 3 show that the weight of AI is 84.3%, indicating that AI can explain most of the increase in the manufacturing employment scale and has a positive promoting effect. The above three methods confirm the robustness of the baseline regression results.

Endogenous problem

Although further control variables are used to alleviate the endogeneity problem caused by missing variables to the greatest extent possible, the bidirectional causal relationship between labour demand and robot installation (for example, enterprises tend to passively adopt the machine replacement strategy in the case of labour shortages and recruitment difficulties) still threatens the accuracy of the statistical inference results in this paper. To eliminate the potential endogeneity problem of the model, the two-stage least squares method (2SLS) was applied. In general, the cost factor that enterprises need to consider when introducing industrial robots is not only the comparative advantage between the efficiency cost of machinery and the costs of equipment and labour wages but also the cost of electricity to maintain the efficient operation of machinery and equipment. Changes in industrial electricity prices indicate that the dynamic conditions between installing robots and hiring workers have changed, and decision-makers need to reweigh the costs and profits of intelligent transformation. Changes in industrial electricity prices can impact the demand for labour by enterprises; this path does not directly affect the labour market but is rather based on the power consumption, work efficiency, and equipment prices of robots. Therefore, industrial electricity prices are exogenous relative to employment, and the demand for robots is correlated.

Electricity production and operation can be divided into power generation, transmission, distribution, and sales. China has realized the integration of exports and distribution, so there are two critical prices in practice: on-grid and sales tariffs (Yu and Liu 2017 ). The government determines the on-grid tariff according to different cost-plus models, and its regulatory policy has roughly proceeded from that of principal and interest repayment, through operating period pricing, to benchmark pricing. The sales price (also known as the catalogue price) is the price of electric energy sold by power grid operators to end users, and its price structure is formed based on the “electric heating price” that was implemented in 1976. There is differentiated pricing between industrial and agricultural electricity. Generally, government departments formulate on-grid tariffs, integrating the interests of power plants, grid enterprises, and end users. As China’s thermal power installed capacity accounts for more than 70% of the installed capacity of generators, the price of coal becomes an essential factor affecting the price of industrial internet access. The pricing strategy for electricity sales is not determined by market-oriented transmission and distribution electricity price, on-grid electricity price, or tax but rather by the goal of “stable growth and ensuring people’s livelihood” (Tang and Yang 2014 ). The externality of the feed-in price is more robust, so the paper chooses the feed-in price as an instrumental variable.

It can be seen from Table 3 that the instrumental variables in the first stage positively affect the robot installation density at the level of 1%. Meanwhile, the results of the validity test of the instrumental variables show that there are no weak instrumental variables or unidentifiable problems with this variable, thus satisfying the principle of correlation and exclusivity. The second-stage results show that robots still positively affect the demand for labour at the 1% level, but the fitting coefficient is smaller than that of the benchmark regression model. In summary, the results of fitting the calculation with the causal inference paradigm still support the conclusion that robots create more jobs and increase the labour demand of enterprises.

Extensibility analysis

Robot adoption and gender bias.

The quantity and quality of labour needed by various industries in the manufacturing sector vary greatly, and labour-intensive and capital-intensive industries have different labour needs. Over the past few decades, the demand for female employees has grown. Female employees obtain more job opportunities and better salaries today (Zhang et al. 2023 ). Female employees may benefit from reducing the content of manual labour jobs, meaning that further study of AI heterogeneity from the perspective of gender bias may be needed. As seen from Table 4 , AI has a significant positive impact on the employment of both male and female practitioners, indicating that AI technology does not have a heterogeneous effect on the dynamic gender structure. By comparing the coefficients of the two (the estimated results for men and those for women), it can be found that robots have a more significant promotion effect on female employees. AI has significantly improved the working environment of front-line workers, reduced the level of labour intensity, enabled people to free themselves of dirty and heavy work tasks, and indirectly improved the job adaptability of female workers. Intellectualization increases the flexibility of the time, place, and manner of work for workers, correspondingly improves the working freedom of female workers, and alleviates the imbalance in the choice between family and career for women to a certain extent (Lu et al. 2023 ). At the same time, women are born with the comparative advantage of cognitive skills that allow them to pay more nuanced attention to work details. By introducing automated technology, companies are increasing the demand for cognitive skills such as mental labour and sentiment analysis, thus increasing the benefits for female workers (Wang and Zhang 2022 ). Flexible employment forms, such as online car hailing, community e-commerce, and online live broadcasting, provide a broader stage for women’s entrepreneurship and employment. According to the “Didi Digital Platform and Female Ecology Research Report”, the number of newly registered female online taxi drivers in China has exceeded 265,000 since 2020, and approximately 60 percent of the heads of the e-commerce platform, Orange Heart, are women.

Industry heterogeneity

Given the significant differences in the combination of factors across the different industries in China’s manufacturing sector, there is also a significant gap in the installation density of robots; even compared to AI density, in industries with different production characteristics, indicating that there may be an opposite employment phenomenon at play. According to the number of employees and their salary level, capital stock, R&D investment, and patent technology, the manufacturing industry is divided into labour-intensive (LI), capital-intensive (CI), and technology-intensive (TI) industries.

As seen from the industry-specific test results displayed in Table 4 , the impact of AI on employment in the three attribute industries is significantly positive, which is consistent with the results of Beier et al. ( 2022 ). In contrast, labour-intensive industries can absorb more workers, and industry practitioners are better able to share digital dividends from these new workers, which is generally in line with expectations (in the labour-intensive case, the regression coefficient of AI on employment is 0.054, which is significantly larger than the regression coefficient of the other two industries). This conclusion shows that enterprises use AI to replace the labour force of procedural and process-based positions in pursuit of cost-effective performance. However, the scale effect generated by improving enterprise production efficiency leads to increased labour demand, namely, productivity and compensation effects. For example, AGV-handling robots are used to replace porters in monotonous and repetitive high-intensity work, thus realizing the uncrewed operation of storage links and the automatic handling of goods, semifinished products, and raw materials in the production process. This reduces the cost of goods storage while improving the efficiency of logistics handling, increasing the capital investment of enterprises in the expansion of market share and extension of the industrial chain.

Mechanism test

To reveal the path mechanism through which AI affects employment, in combination with H2 and H3 and the intermediary effect model constructed with Eq. ( 3 ), the TWFE model was used to fit the results shown in Table 5 .

It can be seen from Table 5 that the fitting coefficients of AI for capital deepening, labour productivity, and division of labour are 0.052, 0.071, and 0.302, respectively, and are all significant at the 1% level, indicating that AI can promote employment through the above three mechanisms, and thus research Hypothesis 2 (H2) is supported. Compared with the workshop and handicraft industry, machine production has driven incomparably broad development in the social division of labour. Intelligent transformation helps to open up the internal and external data chain, improve the combination of production factors, reduce costs and increase efficiency to enable the high-quality development of enterprises. At the macro level, the impact of robotics on social productivity, industrial structure, and product prices affects the labour demand of enterprises. At the micro level, robot technology changes the employment carrier, skill requirements, and employment form of labour and impacts the matching of labour supply and demand. The combination of the price and income effects can drive the impact of technological progress on employment creation. While improving labour productivity, AI technology reduces product production costs. In the case of constant nominal income, the market increases the demand for the product, which in turn drives the expansion of the industrial scale and increases output, resulting in an increase in the demand for labour. At the same time, the emergence of robotics has refined the division of labour. Most importantly, the development of AI technology results in productivity improvements that cannot be matched by pure labour input, which not only enables 24 h automation but also reduces error rates, improves precision, and accelerates production speeds.

Table 5 also shows that the fitting coefficient of AI to virtual agglomeration is 0.141 and significant at the 5% level, indicating that AI and digital technology can promote employment by promoting the agglomeration degree of enterprises in the cloud and network. Research Hypothesis 3 is thus supported. Industrial internet, AI, collaborative robots, and optical fidelity information transmission technology are necessary for the future of the manufacturing industry, and smart factories will become the ultimate direction of manufacturing. Under the intelligent manufacturing model, by leveraging cloud links, industrial robots, and the technological depth needed to achieve autonomous management, the proximity advantage of geographic spatial agglomeration gradually begins to fade. The panconnective features of digital technology break through the situational constraints of work, reshaping the static, linear, and demarcated organizational structure and management modes of the industrial era and increasingly facilitates dynamic, network-based, borderless organizational forms, despite the fact that traditional work tasks can be carried out on a broader network platform employing online office platforms and online meetings. While promoting cost reduction and efficiency increase, such connectivity also creates new occupations that rely on this network to achieve efficient virtual agglomeration. On the other hand, robot technology has also broken the fixed connection between people and jobs, and the previous post matching mode of one person and one specific individual has gradually evolved into an organizational structure involving multiple posts and multiple people, thus providing more diverse and inclusive jobs for different groups.

Conclusions and policy implications

Research conclusion.

The decisive impact of digitization and automation on the functioning of all society’s social subsystems is indisputable. Technological progress alone does not impart any purpose to technology, and its value (consciousness) can only be defined by its application in the social context in which it emerges (Rakowski et al. 2021 ). The recent launch of the intelligent chatbot ChatGPT by the US artificial intelligence company OpenAI, with its powerful word processing capabilities and human-computer interaction, has once again sparked global concerns about its potential impact on employment in related industries. Automation technology represented by intelligent manufacturing profoundly affects the labour supply and demand map and significantly impacts economic and social development. The application of industrial robots is a concrete reflection of the integration of AI technology and industry, and its widespread promotion and popularization in the manufacturing field have resulted in changes in production methods and exerted impacts on the labour market. In this paper, the internal mechanism of AI’s impact on employment is first delineated and then empirical tests based on panel data from 30 provinces (municipalities and autonomous regions, excluding Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan, and Xizang) in China from 2006 to 2020 are subsequently conducted. As mentioned in relation to the theory of “employment compensation,” the research described in this paper shows that the overall impact of AI on employment is positive, revealing a pronounced job creation effect, and the impact of automation technology on the labour market is mainly positively manifested as “icing on the cake.” Our conclusion is consistent with the literature (Sharma and Mishra 2023 ; Feng et al. 2024 ). This conclusion remains after replacing variables, adding missing variables, and controlling for endogeneity problems. The positive role of AI in promoting employment does not have exert opposite effects resulting from gender and industry differences. However, it brings greater digital welfare to female practitioners and workers in labour-intensive industries while relatively reducing the overall proportion of male practitioners in the manufacturing industry. Mechanism analysis shows that AI drives employment through mechanisms that promote capital deepening, the division of labour, and increased labour productivity. The digital trade derived from digital technology and internet platforms has promoted the transformation of traditional industrial agglomeration into virtual agglomeration, the constructed network flow space system is more prone to the free spillover of knowledge, technology, and creativity, and the agglomeration effect and agglomeration mechanism are amplified by geometric multiples. Industrial virtual agglomeration has become a new mechanism and an essential channel through which AI promotes employment, which helps to enhance labour autonomy, improve job suitability and encourage enterprises to share the welfare of labour among “cultivation areas.”

Policy implications

Technology is neutral, and its key lies in its use. Artificial intelligence technology, as an open new general technology, represents significant progress in productivity and is an essential driving force with the potential to boost economic development. However, it also inevitably poses many potential risks and social problems. This study helps to clarify the argument that technology replaces jobs by revealing the impact of automation technology on China’s labour market at the present stage, and its findings alleviate the social anxiety caused by the fear of machine replacement. According to the above research conclusions, the following valuable implications can be obtained.

Investment in AI research and development should be increased, and the high-end development of domestic robots should be accelerated. The development of AI has not only resulted in the improvement of production efficiency but has also triggered a change in industrial structure and labour structure, and it has also generated new jobs as it has replaced human labour. Currently, the impact of AI on employment in China is positive and helps to stabilize employment. Speeding up the development of the information infrastructure, accelerating the intelligent upgrade of the traditional physical infrastructure, and realizing the inclusive promotion of intelligent infrastructure are necessary to ensure efficient development. 5G technology and the development dividend of the digital economy can be used to increase the level of investment in new infrastructure such as cloud computing, the Internet of Things, blockchain, and the industrial internet and to improve the level of intelligent application across the industry. We need to implement the intelligent transformation of old infrastructure, upgrade traditional old infrastructure to smart new infrastructure, and digitally transform traditional forms of infrastructure such as power, reservoirs, rivers, and urban sewer pipes through the employment of sensors and access algorithms to solve infrastructure problems more intelligently. Second, the diversification and agglomeration of industrial lines are facilitated through the transformation of industrial intelligence and automation. At the same time, it is necessary to speed up the process of industrial intelligence and cultivate the prospects of emerging industries and employment carriers, particularly in regard to the development and growth of emerging producer services. The development of domestic robots should be task-oriented and application-oriented, should adhere to the effective transformation of scientific and technological achievements under the guidance of the development of the service economy. A “1 + 2 + N” collaborative innovation ecosystem should be constructed with a focus on cultivating, incubating, and supporting critical technological innovation in each subindustry of the manufacturing industry, optimizing the layout, and forming a matrix multilevel achievement transformation service. We need to improve the mechanisms used for complementing research and production, such as technology investment and authorization. To move beyond standard robot system development technology, the research and development of bionic perception and knowledge, as well as other cutting-edge technologies need to be developed to overcome the core technology “bottleneck” problem.

It is suggested that government departments improve the social security system and stabilize employment through multiple channels. The first channel is the evaluation and monitoring of the potential destruction of the low-end labour force by AI, enabled through the cooperation of the government and enterprises, to build relevant information platforms, improve the transparency of the labour market information, and reasonably anticipate structural unemployment. Big data should be fully leveraged, a sound national employment information monitoring platform should be built, real-time monitoring of the dynamic changes in employment in critical regions, fundamental groups, and key positions should be implemented, employment status information should be released, and employment early warning, forecasting, and prediction should be provided. Second, the backstop role of public service, including human resources departments and social security departments at all levels, should improve the relevant social security system in a timely manner. A mixed-guarantee model can be adopted for the potential unemployed and laws and regulations to protect the legitimate rights and interests of entrepreneurs and temporary employees should be improved. We can gradually expand the coverage of unemployment insurance and basic living allowances. For the extremely poor, unemployed or extreme labour shortage groups, public welfare jobs or special subsidies can be used to stabilize their basic lifestyles. The second is to understand the working conditions of the bottom workers at the grassroots level in greater depth, strengthen the statistical investigation and professional evaluation of AI technology and related jobs, provide skills training, employment assistance, and unemployment subsidies for workers who are unemployed due to the use of AI, and encourage unemployed groups to participate in vocational skills training to improve their applicable skillsets. Workers should be encouraged to use their fragmented time to participate in the gig and sharing economies and achieve flexible employment according to dominant conditions. Finally, a focus should be established on the impact of AI on the changing demand for jobs in specific industries, especially transportation equipment manufacturing and communications equipment, computers, and other electronic equipment manufacturing.

It is suggested that education departments promote the reform of the education and training system and deepen the coordinated development of industry-university research. Big data, the Internet of Things, and AI, as new digital production factors, have penetrated daily economic activities, driving industrial changes and changes in the supply and demand dynamics of the job market. Heterogeneity analysis results confirmed that AI imparts a high level of digital welfare for women and workers in labour-intensive industrial enterprises, but to stimulate the spillover of technology dividends in the whole society, it is necessary to dynamically optimize human capital and improve the adaptability of man-machine collaborative work; otherwise, the disruptive effect of intelligent technology on low-end, routine and programmable work will be obscured. AI has a creativity promoting effect on irregular, creative, and stylized technical positions. Hence, the contradiction between supply and demand in the labour market and the slow transformation of the labour skill structure requires attention. The relevant administrative departments of the state should take the lead in increasing investment in basic research and forming a scientific research division system in which enterprises increase their levels of investment in experimental development and multiple subjects participate in R&D. Relevant departments should clarify the urgent need for talent in the digital economy era, deepen the reform of the education system as a guide, encourage all kinds of colleges and universities to add related majors around AI and big data analysis, accelerate the research on the skill needs of new careers and jobs, and establish a lifelong learning and employment training system that meets the needs of the innovative economy and intelligent society. We need to strengthen the training of innovative, technical, and professional technical personnel, focus on cultivating interdisciplinary talent and AI-related professionals to improve worker adaptability to new industries and technologies, deepen the adjustment of the educational structure, increase the skills and knowledge of perceptual, creative, and social abilities of the workforce, and cultivate the skills needed to perform complex jobs in the future that are difficult to replace by AI. The lifelong education and training system should be improved, and enterprise employees should be encouraged to participate in vocational skills training and cultural knowledge learning through activities such as vocational and technical schools, enterprise universities, and personnel exchanges.

Research limitations

The study used panel data from 30 provinces in China from 2006 to 2020 to examine the impact of AI on employment using econometric models. Therefore, the conclusions obtained in this study are only applicable to the economic reality in China during the sample period. There are three shortcomings in this study. First, only the effect and mechanism of AI in promoting employment from a macro level are investigated in this study, which is limited by the large data particles and small sample data that are factors that reduce the reliability and validity of statistical inference. The digital economy has grown rapidly in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic, and the related industrial structures and job types have been affected by sudden public events. An examination of the impact of AI on employment based on nearly three years of micro-data (particularly the data obtained from field research) is urgent. When conducting empirical analysis, combining case studies of enterprises that are undergoing digital transformation is very helpful. Second, although the two-way fixed effect model and instrumental variable method can reveal conclusions regarding causality to a certain extent, these conclusions are not causal inference in the strict sense. Due to the lack of good policy pilots regarding industrial robots and digital parks, the topic cannot be thoroughly evaluated for determining policy and calculating resident welfare. In future research, researchers can look for policies and systems such as big data pilot zones, intelligent industrial parks, and digital economy demonstration zones to perform policy evaluations through quasinatural experiments. The use of difference in differences (DID), regression discontinuity (RD), and synthetic control method (SCM) to perform regression is beneficial. In addition, the diffusion effect caused by introducing and installing industrial robots leads to the flow of labour between regions, resulting in a potential spatial spillover effect. Although the spatial econometric model is used above, it is mainly used as a robustness test, and the direct effect is considered. This paper has yet to discuss the spatial effect from the perspective of the spatial spillover effect. Last, it is important to note that the digital infrastructure, workforce, and industrial structure differ from country to country. The study focused on a sample of data from China, making the findings only partially applicable to other countries. Therefore, the sample size of countries should be expanded in future studies, and the possible heterogeneity of AI should be explored and compared by classifying different countries according to their stage of development.

Data availability

The data generated during and/or analyzed during the current study are provided in Supplementary File “database”.

Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2018) Low-Skill and High-Skill Automation. J Hum Cap 12(2):204–232. https://doi.org/10.1086/697242

Article   Google Scholar  

Alan H (2023) A systematic bibliometric analysis on the current digital human resources management studies and directions for future research. J Chin Hum Resour Manag 14(1):38–59. https://doi.org/10.47297/wspchrmWSP2040-800502.20231401

Autor D (2019) Work of the past, work of the future. AEA Pap Proc 109(4):1–32. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20191110

Balsmeier B, Woerter M (2019) Is this time different? How digitalization influences job creation and destruction. Res Policy 48(8):103765. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2019.03.010

Beier G, Matthess M, Shuttleworth L, Guan T, Grudzien DIDP, Xue B et al. (2022) Implications of Industry 4.0 on industrial employment: A comparative survey from Brazilian, Chinese, and German practitioners. Technol Soc 70:102028. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2022.102028

Berkers H, Smids J, Nyholm SR, Le Blanc PM (2020) Robotization and meaningful work in logistic warehouses: threats and opportunities. Gedrag Organisatie 33(4):324–347

Google Scholar  

Borland J, Coelli M (2017) Are robots taking our jobs? Aust Economic Rev 50(4):377–397. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8462.12245

Bouattour A, Kalai M, Helali K (2023) The nonlinear impact of technologies import on industrial employment: A panel threshold regression approach. Heliyon 9(10):e20266. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2023.e20266

Article   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Boyd R, Holton RJ (2018) Technology, innovation, employment and power: Does robotics and artificial intelligence really mean social transformation? J Sociol 54(3):331–345. https://doi.org/10.1177/1440783317726591

Chen Z (2023) Ethics and discrimination in artificial intelligence-enabled recruitment practices. Humanities Soc Sci Commun 10:567. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-023-02079-x

Dixon J, Hong B, Wu L (2021) The robot revolution: Managerial and employment consequences for firms. Manag Sci 67(9):5586–5605. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2020.3812

Duan SX, Deng H, Wibowo S (2023) Exploring the impact of digital work on work-life balance and job performance: a technology affordance perspective. Inf Technol People 36(5):2009–2029. https://doi.org/10.1108/ITP-01-2021-0013

Duan X, Zhang Q (2023) Industrial digitization, virtual agglomeration and total factor productivity. J Northwest Norm Univ(Soc Sci) 60(1):135–144. https://doi.org/10.16783/j.cnki.nwnus.2023.01.016

Dunn M (2020) Making gigs work: digital platforms, job quality and worker motivations. N. Technol Work Employ 35(2):232–249. https://doi.org/10.1111/ntwe.12167

Fabo B, Karanovic J, Dukova K (2017) In search of an adequate European policy response to the platform economy. Transf: Eur Rev Labour Res 23(2):163–175. https://doi.org/10.1177/1024258916688861

Feng R, Shen C, Guo Y (2024) Digital finance and labor demand of manufacturing enterprises: Theoretical mechanism and heterogeneity analysis. Int Rev Econ Financ 89(Part A):17–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2023.07.065

Filippi E, Bannò M, Trento S (2023) Automation technologies and their impact on employment: A review, synthesis and future research agenda. Technol Forecast Soc Change 191:122448. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2023.122448

Fokam DNDT, Kamga BF, Nchofoung TN (2023) Information and communication technologies and employment in developing countries: Effects and transmission channels. Telecommun Policy 47(8):102597. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2023.102597

Forsythe E, Kahn LB, Lange F, Wiczer D (2022) Where have all the workers gone? Recalls, retirements, and reallocation in the COVID recovery. Labour Econ 78:102251. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2022.102251

Fossen FM, Sorgner A (2022) New digital technologies and heterogeneous wage and employment dynamics in the United States: Evidence from individual-level data. Technol Forecast Soc Change 175:121381. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2021.121381

Frey CB, Osborne MA (2017) The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerisation? Technol Forecast Soc Change 114:254–280. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.08.019

Gardberg M, Heyman F, Norbäck P, Persson L (2020) Digitization-based automation and occupational dynamics. Econ Lett 189:109032. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2020.109032

Ge P, Zhao Z (2023) The rise of robots and employment change: 2009–2017. J Renmin Univ China 37(1):102–115

Graf H, Mohamed H (2024) Robotization and employment dynamics in German manufacturing value chains. Struct Change Economic Dyn 68:133–147. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2023.10.014

Han J, Yan X, Wei N (2022) Study on regional differences of the impact of artificial intelligence on China’s employment skill structure. Northwest Popul J 43(3):45–57. https://doi.org/10.15884/j.cnki.issn.1007-0672.2022.03.004

Article   CAS   Google Scholar  

Huang M, Rust RT (2018) Artificial intelligence in service. J Serv Res 21(2):155–172. https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670517752459

Jiang T (2022) Mediating effects and moderating effects in causal inference. China Ind Econ 410(5):100–120. https://doi.org/10.19581/j.cnki.ciejournal.2022.05.005

Article   MathSciNet   Google Scholar  

Jin X, Ma B, Zhang H (2023) Impact of fast internet access on employment: Evidence from a broadband expansion in China. China Econ Rev 81:102038. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2023.102038

Jetha A, Bonaccio S, Shamaee A, Banks CG, Bültmann U, Smith PM et al. (2023) Divided in a digital economy: Understanding disability employment inequities stemming from the application of advanced workplace technologies. SSM - Qual Res Health 3:100293. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ssmqr.2023.100293

Josifidis K, Supic N (2018) Income polarization of the US working class: An institutionalist view. J Econ Issues 52(2):498–508. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2018.1469929

Kirov V, Malamin B (2022) Are translators afraid of artificial intelligence? Societies 12(2):70. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc12020070

Kolade O, Owoseni A (2022) Employment 5.0: The work of the future and the future of work. Technol Soc 71:102086. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2022.102086

Li L, Mo Y, Zhou G (2022) Platform economy and China’ s labor market: structural transformation and policy challenges. China Econ J 15(2):139–152. https://doi.org/10.1080/17538963.2022.2067685

Li Q, Zhang R (2022) Study on the challenges and countermeasures of coordinated development of quantity and quality of employment under the new technology-economy paradigm. J Xiangtan Univ(Philos Soc Sci) 46(5):42–45+58. https://doi.org/10.13715/j.cnki.jxupss.2022.05.019

Li Z, Hong Y, Zhang Z (2021) The empowering and competition effects of the platform-based sharing economy on the supply and demand sides of the labor market. J Manag Inf Syst 38(1):140–165. https://doi.org/10.1080/07421222.2021.1870387

Liu L (2018) Occupational therapy in the fourth industrial revolution. Can J Occup Ther 85(4):272–283. https://doi.org/10.1177/0008417418815179

Article   ADS   Google Scholar  

Liu N, Gu X, Lei CK (2022) The equilibrium effects of digital technology on banking, production, and employment. Financ Res Lett 49:103196. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103196

Liu Y, Peng J (2023) The impact of “AI unemployment” on contemporary youth and its countermeasures. Youth Exploration 241(1):43–51. https://doi.org/10.13583/j.cnki.issn1004-3780.2023.01.004

Lu J, Xiao Q, Wang T (2023) Does the digital economy generate a gender dividend for female employment? Evidence from China. Telecommun Policy 47(6):102545. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2023.102545

Luo J, Zhuo W, Xu B (2023). The bigger, the better? Optimal NGO size of human resources and governance quality of entrepreneurship in circular economy. Management Decision ahead-of-print. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-03-2023-0325

Männasoo K, Pareliussen JK, Saia A (2023) Digital capacity and employment outcomes: Microdata evidence from pre- and post-COVID-19 Europe. Telemat Inform 83:102024. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tele.2023.102024

Michau JB (2013) Creative destruction with on-the-job search. Rev Econ Dyn 16(4):691–707. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2012.10.011

Morgan J (2019) Will we work in twenty-first century capitalism? A critique of the fourth industrial revolution literature. Econ Soc 48(3):371–398. https://doi.org/10.1080/03085147.2019.1620027

Nam T (2019) Technology usage, expected job sustainability, and perceived job insecurity. Technol Forecast Soc Change 138:155–165. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2018.08.017

Ndubuisi G, Otioma C, Tetteh GK (2021) Digital infrastructure and employment in services: Evidence from Sub-Saharan African countries. Telecommun Policy 45(8):102153. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2021.102153

Ni B, Obashi A (2021) Robotics technology and firm-level employment adjustment in Japan. Jpn World Econ 57:101054. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.japwor.2021.101054

Nikitas A, Vitel AE, Cotet C (2021) Autonomous vehicles and employment: An urban futures revolution or catastrophe? Cities 114:103203. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2021.103203

Novella R, Rosas-Shady D, Alvarado A (2023) Are we nearly there yet? New technology adoption and labor demand in Peru. Sci Public Policy 50(4):565–578. https://doi.org/10.1093/scipol/scad007

Oschinski A, Wyonch R (2017). Future shock?: the impact of automation on Canada’s labour market.C.D. Howe Institute Commentary working paper

Polak P (2021) Welcome to the digital era—the impact of AI on business and society. Society 58:177–178. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12115-021-00588-6

Rakowski R, Polak P, Kowalikova P (2021) Ethical aspects of the impact of AI: the status of humans in the era of artificial intelligence. Society 58:196–203. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12115-021-00586-8

Ramos ME, Garza-Rodríguez J, Gibaja-Romero DE (2022) Automation of employment in the presence of industry 4.0: The case of Mexico. Technol Soc 68:101837. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2021.101837

Reljic J, Evangelista R, Pianta M (2021). Digital technologies, employment, and skills. Industrial and Corporate Change dtab059. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtab059

Schultz DE (1998) The death of distance—How the communications revolution will change our lives. Int Mark Rev 15(4):309–311. https://doi.org/10.1108/imr.1998.15.4.309.1

Sharma C, Mishra RK (2023) Imports, technology, and employment: Job creation or creative destruction. Manag Decis Econ 44(1):152–170. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3671

Shen Y, Yang Z (2023) Chasing green: The synergistic effect of industrial intelligence on pollution control and carbon reduction and its mechanisms. Sustainability 15(8):6401. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15086401

Spencer DA (2023) Technology and work: Past lessons and future directions. Technol Soc 74:102294. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2023.102294

Sun W, Liu Y (2023) Research on the influence mechanism of artificial intelligence on labor market. East China Econ Manag 37(3):1–9. https://doi.org/10.19629/j.cnki.34-1014/f.220706008

Tan H, Xia C (2022) Digital trade reshapes the theory and model of industrial agglomeration — From geographic agglomeration to online agglomeration. Res Financial Econ Issues 443(6):43–52. https://doi.org/10.19654/j.cnki.cjwtyj.2022.06.004

Tang J, Yang J (2014) Research on the economic impact of the hidden subsidy of sales price and reform. China Ind Econ 321(12):5–17. https://doi.org/10.19581/j.cnki.ciejournal.2014.12.001

Tschang FT, Almirall E (2021) Artificial intelligence as augmenting automation: Implications for employment. Acad Manag Perspect 35(4):642–659. https://doi.org/10.5465/amp.2019.0062

Wang PX, Kim S, Kim M (2023) Robot anthropomorphism and job insecurity: The role of social comparison. J Bus Res 164:114003. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2023.114003

Wang L, Hu S, Dong Z (2022) Artificial intelligence technology, Task attribute and occupational substitutable risk: Empirical evidence from the micro-level. J Manag World 38(7):60–79. https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2022.0094

Wang R, Liang Q, Li G (2018) Virtual agglomeration: a new form of spatial organization with the deep integration of new generation information technology and real economy. J Manag World 34(2):13–21. https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2018.02.002

Wang X, Zhu X, Wang Y (2022) TheImpactofRobotApplicationonManufacturingEmployment. J Quant Technol Econ 39(4):88–106. https://doi.org/10.13653/j.cnki.jqte.2022.04.002

Wang Y, Zhang Y (2022) Dual employment effect of digital economy and higher quality employment development. Expanding Horiz 231(3):43–50

Wang Y, Zhang Y, Liu J (2022) Digital finance and carbon emissions: an empirical test based on micro data and machine learning model. China Popul,Resour Environ 32(6):1–11

Wen J, Liu Y (2021) Uncertainty of new employment form: Digital labor in platform capital space and the reflection on it. J Zhejiang Gongshang Univ 171(6):92–106. https://doi.org/10.14134/j.cnki.cn33-1337/c.2021.06.009

Wong SI, Fieseler C, Kost D (2020) Digital labourers’ proactivity and the venture for meaningful work: Fruitful or fruitless? J-of-Occup-and-Organ-Psychol 93(4):887–911. https://doi.org/10.1111/joop.12317

Wu B, Yang W (2022) Empirical test of the impact of the digital economy on China’s employment structure. Financ Res Lett 49:103047. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2022.103047

Wu Q (2023) Sustainable growth through industrial robot diffusion: Quasi-experimental evidence from a Bartik shift-share design. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change Early Access https://doi.org/10.1111/ecot.12367

Xie M, Dong L, Xia Y, Guo J, Pan J, Wang H (2022) Does artificial intelligence affect the pattern of skill demand? Evidence from Chinese manufacturing firms. Econ Model 96:295–309. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2021.01.009

Yan X, Zhu K, Ma C (2020) Employment under robot Impact: Evidence from China manufacturing. Stat Res 37(1):74–87. https://doi.org/10.19343/j.cnki.11-1302/c.2020.01.006

Yang CH (2022) How artificial intelligence technology affects productivity and employment: Firm-level evidence from Taiwan. Res Policy 51(6):104536. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2022.104536

Yang Z, Shen Y (2023) The impact of intelligent manufacturing on industrial green total factor productivity and its multiple mechanisms. Front Environ Sci 10:1058664. https://doi.org/10.3389/fenvs.2022.1058664

Yoon C (2023) Technology adoption and jobs: The effects of self-service kiosks in restaurants on labor outcomes. Technol Soc 74:102336. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2023.102336

Yu L, Liu Y (2017) Consumers’ welfare in China’s electric power industry competition. Res Econ Manag 38(8):55–64. https://doi.org/10.13502/j.cnki.issn1000-7636.2017.08.006

Zhang Q, Zhang F, Mai Q (2023) Robot adoption and labor demand: A new interpretation from external competition. Technol Soc 74:102310. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2023.102310

Zhang Y, Li X (2022) The new digital infrastructure, gig employment and spatial spillover effect. China Bus Mark 36(11):103–117. https://doi.org/10.14089/j.cnki.cn11-3664/f.2022.11.010

Article   MathSciNet   CAS   Google Scholar  

Zhang Z (2023a) The impact of the artificial intelligence industry on the number and structure of employments in the digital economy environment. Technol Forecast Soc Change 197:122881. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2023.122881

Zhao L, Zhao X (2017) Is AI endangering human job opportunities?—From a perspective of marxism. J Hebei Univ Econ Bus 38(6):17–22. https://doi.org/10.14178/j.cnki.issn1007-2101.2017.06.004

Zhou S, Chen B (2022) Robots and industrial employment: Based on the perspective of subtask model. Stat Decis 38(23):85–89. https://doi.org/10.13546/j.cnki.tjyjc.2022.23.016

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was financially supported by the Natural Science Foundation of Fujian Province (Grant No. 2022J01320).

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Institute of Quantitative Economics, Huaqiao University, Xiamen, 361021, China

Yang Shen & Xiuwu Zhang

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

YS: Data analysis, Writing – original draft, Software, Methodology, Formal analysis; XZ: Data collection; Supervision, Project administration, Writing – review & editing, Funding acquisition. All authors substantially contributed to the article and accepted the published version of the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yang Shen .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare no competing interests.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies featuring human participants performed by any of the authors.

Informed consent

This study does not contain any study with human participants performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary information

Rights and permissions.

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Shen, Y., Zhang, X. The impact of artificial intelligence on employment: the role of virtual agglomeration. Humanit Soc Sci Commun 11 , 122 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-024-02647-9

Download citation

Received : 23 August 2023

Accepted : 09 January 2024

Published : 18 January 2024

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-024-02647-9

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

the job market essay

Discrimination in the Labor Market Essay

Introduction, market oriented approach, the embedded approach, point of agreement, the future of impacted groups, works cited.

Though a lot of effort has been dedicated in ensuring that discrimination along any ideology is eliminated, discrimination is still perpetrated in various sectors of the economy. Studies show that in the American labor market, equality is yet to be achieved. Minority groups still account for a very small percentage of people employed.

The majority of the unemployed people come from the minority ethnic groups including the African-Americans, the Spaniards and the Latinos (Royster 37). This kind of discrimination has been there since time immemorial and is expressed in different forms including wage difference, and allocation of employment opportunities.

As a result, there are two schools of thought, the market oriented perspective and the embedded perspective, which try to explain the racial discrimination in the labor market. Though these two schools of thought have great differences, they concur on some explanations.

The market oriented approach argues that the disparities in the labor market are normal results of the forces of demand and supply. According to this approach, the market has ways of balancing itself and these will always cause disparities (Waldinger and Michael 85).

The minorities lack the required experience and expertise to carry out some duties thus, compelling employers to look for the best alternative. It should be noted that each employer is out to maximize the returns from each unit of input and will, therefore, employ only the best suited inputs including human capital. In addition, it is argued that people from the minority races are few in number. Therefore, it is quite natural that they will be statistically few in various sections of the labor market.

Instead of the minorities complaining about being unable to get certain employment opportunities or earn a specific salary, they should react to information from the market. Consequently, they should invest and train in professions where salaries are high because these professions are highly valued (Vallas, William and Amy 210).

On the same note, they should advance their education standards so that they can compete favorably with the others. Notably, the market oriented perspective is against any artificial interference in the name of balancing the labor market, arguing that this will cause inefficiency. As long as, the minorities are not ready to embrace the reality in the labor market, the elite class will continue to control resources thus leading to further discrimination (Waldinger and Michael 218).

On the other hand, the social embedded perspective argues that discrimination in today’s labor market stems from traditions that have been passed down through generations. The cultural values that are passed to each generation come with vested interests, which sometimes surpass the individual feeling that one may have towards a given ethnic group or race.

According to this perspective, the decline of social ties among people has paved way to social conflicts with the economically strong white group wanting to control the industrial economy (Royster 106). As a result, racial discrimination has emerged, though in a different form from what people were used to. The state has painfully added legitimacy, through its bureaucratic institutions, to actions which seem neutral but are actually improved forms of racism.

Proponents of this perspective argue that discrimination that is witnessed nowadays has its roots in the traditional social structure. Additionally, discrimination has been known to occur not because of the racist ideologies per se, but as a result of impartial circumstances.

Furthermore, the inherent practices of colonialism and privileges and traditions exercised by small white people have enhanced discrimination against minorities (Royster 108). In this regard, socially embedded perspective depicts that social norms to which people subscribe make it really hard for minorities to access labor.

Society is so vividly similar to what it was traditionally and cases of stereotyping are still prevalent. Therefore, some people have negative attitude towards certain races just because the race was considered inferior in ancient times (Vallas, William and Amy 198). Moreover, the society is also divided into economic and political groups where the superior groups still look down upon the inferior groups leading to discrimination.

Despite the two schools of thought having different views on the explanations of racial discrimination, they both agree on some points. To begin with, the two agree that lack of skills play a vital role in enhancing discrimination in various sections of the labor market. In this regard, it is argued that the minority groups have for a long period not taken education seriously (Royster 69).

Consequently, when employment opportunities arise it is found that the minority races cannot favorably compete for the same. The two schools of thought, therefore, agree that minority races also bear the blame of allowing discrimination in the labor market.

Another point of concurrence is that class distinction exists within the society and this still influences people’s decisions and actions. There are mechanisms in place which contrary to their objectives, only serve to separate the minority from others.

Instead of saving the minority from racist activities, these mechanisms deepen the miseries of minor races by exposing them to discrimination (Waldinger and Michael 229). In order to ensure that they increase their incomes and maintain their status quo as well, the ruling class will ensure the proletariats are not economically empowered. Therefore, the ruling class discriminates against other people to take care of their vested interests.

Discrimination is a reality that cannot be assumed in our society. Its there within our vicinity, and in one way or another it affects each one of us. It is very unfair to other people if they are eliminated from certain competitions just because of their skin color. The fact that one belongs to a given race does not make the person superior or inferior.

Unfortunately, the efforts put in place to eliminate discrimination are not doing much in curbing the vice and more needs to be done. Social embedded perspective argues that discrimination results from the basic structures of the society (Royster 105). Consequently, to eliminate discrimination the basics of the American society need to change.

People must be educated to get over their stereotypes and evaluate all people objectively. Minimization of the income gap is important to eliminate class distinction and thus avoid various causes of discrimination.

Since the market oriented perspectives argues that disparities witnessed are due to action of the market forces, it will be crucial to consider what the market requires. In this regard, it is upon the minority to invest heavily in education and thus enhance their employability.

On the same note, the minority need to join labor unions which will enable them to fight for better payments as well as their rights (Vallas, William and Amy 243). However, the government also needs to intervene and institute laws which will ensure that people with the same qualifications are paid equally regardless of their skin color. Essentially, it is a combination of strategies that will help in eliminating discrimination present in our society.

Royster, Deirde A. Race and the Invisible Hand: How White Networks Exclude Black Men From Blue-Collar Jobs . Berkeley: University of California Press, 2003. Print.

Vallas, Steven P., William Finlay and Amy S. Wharton. The Sociology of Work: Structures and Inequalities . New York: Oxford University Press, 2009. Print.

Waldinger, Roger and Michael I. Litcher. How the Other Half Works: Immigration and the Social Organization of Labor . Berkeley: University of California Press, 2003. Print.

  • The Innovative Magic Box: Underlying Risks & Mitigation Strategies
  • Surgically Implanted Smart Chips
  • ABC Inc.: Lack of Equal Employment Opportunities of Asians
  • Conscientiousness in the Workplace
  • Equal Employment in the Workplace
  • Human Resource Management: Workforce Diversity
  • Violence in the Workplace
  • Managing a Culturally Diverse Workforce
  • Chicago (A-D)
  • Chicago (N-B)

IvyPanda. (2019, April 10). Discrimination in the Labor Market. https://ivypanda.com/essays/discrimination-in-the-labor-market/

"Discrimination in the Labor Market." IvyPanda , 10 Apr. 2019, ivypanda.com/essays/discrimination-in-the-labor-market/.

IvyPanda . (2019) 'Discrimination in the Labor Market'. 10 April.

IvyPanda . 2019. "Discrimination in the Labor Market." April 10, 2019. https://ivypanda.com/essays/discrimination-in-the-labor-market/.

1. IvyPanda . "Discrimination in the Labor Market." April 10, 2019. https://ivypanda.com/essays/discrimination-in-the-labor-market/.

Bibliography

IvyPanda . "Discrimination in the Labor Market." April 10, 2019. https://ivypanda.com/essays/discrimination-in-the-labor-market/.

To read this content please select one of the options below:

Please note you do not have access to teaching notes, the impacts of artificial intelligence (ai) on jobs: an industry perspective.

Strategic HR Review

ISSN : 1475-4398

Article publication date: 20 May 2021

Issue publication date: 13 July 2021

This paper aims to explore the impacts of artificial intelligence (AI) on jobs.

Design/methodology/approach

The authors followed rapid review guidelines. The authors collected industry and government reports published prior and up to August 2017 in Google and Google Scholar using combination of key words: “job automation” or “work automation” with technology keywords: “artificial intelligence,” “machine learning,” etc. In total, 11 were included in this research.

The use of AI technologies will impact jobs in the near future as some job tasks are automated. AI is likely to substitute both, routine and nonroutine tasks. It is expected that humans and robots would work together in ways never imaginable. Changes in employability skills are expected. Because of the magnitude of these impacts on jobs, consulted reports call for concerted solutions that go beyond organizations’ and industry’s boundaries to include other relevant stakeholders. Moreover, organizations will have to rethink their human resource (HR) function to realign its expertise to the reality of AI.

Practical implications

In this context, the HR function will have to understand the dynamics that generate the impacts of these technologies in a workplace, to anticipate changes and actively contribute to creating an organizational environment that will facilitate the collaboration between human workers and complex digital agents, while ensuring compliance with labor and employment laws and supporting strategic organizational objectives.

Originality/value

This paper contributes to the debate on ongoing concerns by providing a synthesis of relevant professional literature.

  • HR function
  • Artificial intelligence (AI)
  • Jobs automation

Poba-Nzaou, P. , Galani, M. , Uwizeyemungu, S. and Ceric, A. (2021), "The impacts of artificial intelligence (AI) on jobs: an industry perspective", Strategic HR Review , Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 60-65. https://doi.org/10.1108/SHR-01-2021-0003

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Emerald Publishing Limited

Related articles

We’re listening — tell us what you think, something didn’t work….

Report bugs here

All feedback is valuable

Please share your general feedback

Join us on our journey

Platform update page.

Visit emeraldpublishing.com/platformupdate to discover the latest news and updates

Questions & More Information

Answers to the most commonly asked questions here

Fat shaming in the job market

post img

Checked : Eric H. , Gracie B.

Latest Update 26 Jan, 2024

Table of content

Being overweight has been viewed in various perspectives all around the world and throughout history. In some past civilizations, especially where money and food were scarce, people would see a fat figure as a sign of prosperity and having enough to eat. Plump bodies were considered to represent beauty, fertility and wealth. On the contrary, over just the past few decades in the modern developed world, people began to view being fat not as a sign of prosperity, but a source of shame.

If we look back into history, we can see evidence of deities and symbolic figures depicted as fat people. For example, we have the figurine of Venus of Willendorf, uncovered in Austria in 1908, believed to have been created thousands of years ago. Although the face is indistinct, the body is anatomically correct – and very obviously overweight. Over the past century, she has been used as a symbol of fertility, a toy, or a teaching device for   pregnant women . The Venus is not the only fat figurine in history. There are also the “Fat Ladies of Malta”, another set of figurines of overweight female figures, mostly with no heads or very small heads relative to their body size. Often found in burial sites and shrines, historians have suggested that these Maltese figurines held some symbol of importance to the people of that civilization. Additionally, ancient fat figurines were not all women. There is also a jade carving from Guatemala believed to have been created around 700 BC, depicting the “Fat Lord and Frog”. This man is obese and must have constituted some importance in society then, as common folk would not have their images carved into jade.

The very fact that these figurines exist prove that people in the past may have held fatness to some level of reverence. At the very least, it is unlikely they thought being fat was a bad thing. How, then, have we conceived these notions about people’s mass today? Why is being fat a negative thing in modern society? And, more importantly, are we allowing our delusions of a person’s body shape to influence decisions that are supposed to be perfectly logical?

“Nothing tastes as good as skinny feels.” That was what the model Kate Moss said in 2009, resulting in a lot of public backlash. Critics argued that she should not encourage this kind of thinking, which could easily cause many more eating disorders among her numerous young fans. Unfortunately, Moss is not the only person who has said such statements regarding plump bodies. Our society, particularly that of America, has developed such views toward fat people and in turn influenced others to label fatness as a bad thing.

There is also no denying that being fat can come with several health complications. And unlike most people’s flaws or shortcomings, a fat figure is plain for all to see. Some people may argue that fat shaming stems from a desire to help people to minimize their health risks, but is this entirely true? Most likely, people who insult others as “fat” are probably not worrying about their health concerns, and besides, insulting others can have detrimental effects on one’s health anyway.

Fatness has also evolved into a sign of laziness. In the past, people struggled to feed themselves, and one who had enough to eat to the point of becoming plump was considered lucky. However, in today’s society, food is readily available to almost anyone in developed countries. Instead of finding food, the focus has shifted to having enough time to work out and prepare healthier meals to have a slimmer body, suggesting the notion that a fat person is lazy, weak and lacks the willpower to lose some weight. Of course, we know that while a sedentary lifestyle could possibly lead to someone becoming fat, others are simply naturally plump even if they try to slim down. Some people are born on the chubbier side, while others have a low metabolism rate and easily gain weight from simply living a normal lifestyle. Yet others may be under medications with side effects that cause them to gain weight or have difficulty losing it. None of these factors really link to the reasoning that a fat person is lazy or weak, but the subconscious association is still there, perhaps even in fat people themselves.

Perhaps the evolved notions regarding body mass can be due to people’s self-criticism in finding greener pastures. When the majority of people are thin, they look to plumpness as a desirable outcome. But when the scales have shifted and the majority of people now have no trouble putting on a few pounds, they then look to thinness as a desirable outcome.

It is undeniable that all these assumptions about fat people in today’s society have led to fat shaming in job culture. For one, fat people are generally less likely to be offered a job, even if they have the exact same qualifications as a slimmer person. Studies on subconscious discrimination have shown that job interviewers were more likely to follow up with someone who was not fat compared to someone who was fat, even if the interviewers themselves did not mindfully discriminate against fat people in general. Society has ingrained in us a deep mindset that people find difficult to shake, regardless of their voluntary views toward fat people.

image banner

We Will Promptly Compose an Essay for You

One possible reason why employers may be reluctant to hire fat people is that the employers could be concerned about a fat person’s health and whether they will be able to work as effectively as anyone else. Given that the general stereotype for fat people is that they are lazy and weak, most people who grew up surrounded with these stereotypes in their society tend to form similar subconscious associations when they see a picture of a fat person, without ever meeting them in person or talking to them.

It is easy to use reason to say that these assumptions are baseless, but much more difficult to change an entire society’s way of thinking. After all, from observing how the shift in society’s attitude towards fat people has occurred, it is likely that we would need a complete turn around of work and food availability in developed countries to trigger such an evolution again. In our “golden age” now, where people in developed societies live a life of luxury and accessibility, we may never know hardship in our lifetimes. As such, people may be inevitably shaming fat figures in the job market for years to come, regardless of how much awareness spreads about the discrimination of others. Are we content to sit idly by and allow these blanket ideas to drive our society, or will it ever be possible to turn the situation around again? Are we willing to give up a cushy life just to make a stand for humanity?

Looking for an Experienced Essay Writer?

creator avatar

  • Gettysburg College Bachelor of Music (BM)

No reviews yet, be the first to write your comment

Write your review

Thanks for review.

It will be published after moderation

Latest News

article image

Humanistic Perspectives on the Arts

26 Jan, 2024

article image

Bayesian Games

article image

New historicism

IMAGES

  1. Main essay oswald stuart "Translation Job Market"

    the job market essay

  2. Labour Market Essay

    the job market essay

  3. Remote Working: How COVID-19 Escalated the Shift Within the Job Market

    the job market essay

  4. Understanding the job market

    the job market essay

  5. (DOC) In today’s job market it is far more important to have practical

    the job market essay

  6. Labour Market Trends Essay

    the job market essay

VIDEO

  1. The Job Market Is WAY Worse Than You Think

COMMENTS

  1. The Job Market in the 21st Century

    The Job Market in the 21st Century Essay. The professional landscape is always changing, answering to global trends and developments within the economic, political, and social spheres. Some professions come into prominence as their relevance increases, while others fall into obscurity. Naturally, both the development of tech and the increased ...

  2. Job Market: Definition, Measurement, Example

    Job Market: The job market is the market in which employers search for employees and employees search for jobs. The job market is not a physical place as much as a concept demonstrating the ...

  3. PDF The Ten Most Important Rules of Writing Your Job Market Paper

    The Ten Most Important Rules of Writing Your Job Market Paper. Rule #1: You will probably not have a Nobel Prize winning idea. Theorem #1: It is always possible to transform a good idea into a great paper and a superb presentation. Theorem #2: Even if your idea is Nobel-worthy, you can always make it into a poorly written paper and a lousy ...

  4. Job Market

    Job Market. Where individuals search for job opportunities and employers look for employees. Over 1.8 million professionals use CFI to learn accounting, financial analysis, modeling and more. Start with a free account to explore 20+ always-free courses and hundreds of finance templates and cheat sheets.

  5. Job Market Essays: Examples, Topics, & Outlines

    Kuwaiti Public and Private Sector Job Market. PAGES 6 WORDS 1863. Kuwait labor market is one of the major components of the country's economy and has played a significant role in current economic problems in the country. Since the beginning of the oil era in Kuwait, the country has increasingly relied on a growing workforce (labor market ...

  6. SURVIVING IN TODAY'S JOB MARKET Essay

    SURVIVING IN TODAY'S JOB MARKET Essay. Decent Essays. 1340 Words. 6 Pages. Open Document. The job market today is difficult for both employees and employers. It hurts emotionally and financially to lose a job, and it is equally painful to have to terminate someone. Both sides struggle. If you work for an organization that may be facing ...

  7. Job Market Essay Examples

    The market is rapidly evolving, leading to more job opportunities. Such changes have been driven by technological advancement and the shifting of workforce dynamics. Individuals need to embrace differences and ensure that they optimize them for better allocation of resources. In the recent past, the advancement of technology has disrupted ...

  8. Competitive Job Market: Definition and Tips for Standing Out

    A competitive job market refers to the amount of competition there is for open positions. A job market can shrink or grow based on the demand for labor and the number of employees available in the economy. When there is a competitive job market, it generally means there are more employees waiting to fill roles than there are positions available ...

  9. Economic Trends And The Job Market Economics Essay

    Some economists have world wide adopted this indicator as a measure of recession in the economy. In the job market, the low - skilled, low - educated and young workers form the most vulnerable group to unemployment during a recession or a depression. Previous experiences have demonstrated that, job market is the most affected of other ...

  10. Job Market Signaling*

    The essay is based on the author's doctoral dissertation ("Market Signalling: The Informational Structure of Job Markets and Related Phenomena," Ph.D. thesis, Harvard University, 1972), forthcoming as a book entitled Market Signaling: Information Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening Processes in the Harvard Economic Studies Series, Harvard University Press.

  11. Addressing the mismatch between colleges and the job market (essay)

    Peter Stokes explores the mismatch in information and results between colleges and the employment market. Recently, the McKinsey Center for Government released the second in its "Education to Employment" series of the reports. The first, " Education to Employment: Designing a System that Works ," released in December 2012, looked at ...

  12. How Will The Job Market Change in The Future

    On the socio-economic front, it is clear that ageing populations worldwide will create many jobs in the caregiving sector of the market. The US Bureau for Labour Statistics expects jobs for Home Health Aides and Personal Care Aids to grown 47% and 39% respectively in the next decade (ref 4 - new), the highest of all their categories.

  13. (PDF) AI AND THE JOB MARKET

    The impact of artificial intelligence (AI) on the job market continues to be a topic of debate. While AI has been perceived as a potential threat to employment, it also presents opportunities. for ...

  14. The Impact of Artificial Intelligence on the Job Market: Expository Essay

    The most conspicuous and immediate consequence of AI in the job market is the automation revolution. AI-powered algorithms and machines can efficiently execute routine, repetitive tasks, often outperforming humans in terms of speed and precision. This has led to the displacement of human workers in various sectors such as manufacturing, data ...

  15. The Impact of AI on The Job Market: Key Insights

    Article. Artificial intelligence (AI) is transforming industries as organizations leverage the latest technologies to drive efficiencies and make smarter data-driven decisions. A common concern is that AI will replace workers, but, at least so far, these fears haven't borne out. Rather than replacing workers, AI is reshaping the job market by ...

  16. Board-Certified Behavior Analyst at Job Market Essay

    In the United States, the average BCBA pay is around $62,000 per year and the worst ten percent make $47,000 per year, whereas the top ten percent get $97,000 per year, excluding bonuses (Epstein, 2020). BCBAs at the entry-level earn around $57,000 per year, with annual wages rising in the following order: Humble beginnings: $60,000, immediate ...

  17. the job market Essay

    Job Market Essay. According to the article, employment of accountants and auditors is projected to grow 13 percent from 2012 to 2022, about as fast as the average for all occupations. Over the five years to November 2018, the number of job openings for Accountants is expected to be greater than 50,000. Job openings can arise from employment ...

  18. The impact of artificial intelligence on employment: the role of

    Among factors, AI and robotics exert a particularly significant impact on the manufacturing job market, and industry-related jobs will face a severe unemployment problem due to the disruptive ...

  19. Discrimination in the Labor Market

    Introduction. Though a lot of effort has been dedicated in ensuring that discrimination along any ideology is eliminated, discrimination is still perpetrated in various sectors of the economy. Studies show that in the American labor market, equality is yet to be achieved. Minority groups still account for a very small percentage of people employed.

  20. Importance of English in the Job Market

    Importance of English in the Job Market. "Language is the road map of a culture. It tells you where its people come from and where they are going.". ‒ Rita Mae Brown. English is the fastest ...

  21. The impacts of artificial intelligence (AI) on jobs: an industry

    Findings. The use of AI technologies will impact jobs in the near future as some job tasks are automated. AI is likely to substitute both, routine and nonroutine tasks. It is expected that humans and robots would work together in ways never imaginable. Changes in employability skills are expected. Because of the magnitude of these impacts on ...

  22. Fat shaming in the job market

    Essay on Fat shaming in the job market. It is easy to use reason to say that these assumptions are baseless, but much more difficult to change an entire society's way of thinking. ... As such, people may be inevitably shaming fat figures in the job market for years to come, regardless of how much awareness spreads about the discrimination of ...